The walk we have been taking has led
us only through the heart of the city, in which were
the public buildings, temples, basílicas, pórticos,
etc., of which we hear so much in Latin literature.
It was on the hills which are spurs of the plain beyond,
and which look down over the Forum and the Campus
Martius, the Caelian, Esquiline, and Quirinal,
with the hollows lying between them, and also on the
Aventine by the river, that the mass of the population
lived. The most ancient fortification of completed
Rome, the so-called Servian wall and agger,
enclosed a singularly large space, larger, we are told,
than the walls of any old city in Italy; it is
likely that a good part of this space was long unoccupied
by houses, and served to shelter the cattle of the
farmers living outside, when an enemy was threatening
attack. But in Cicero’s time, as to-day,
all this space was covered with dwellings; and as
the centre of the city came to be occupied with public
buildings, erected on sites often bought from private
owners, the houses were gradually pushed out along
the roads beyond the walls. Exactly the same
process has been going on for centuries in the University
city of Oxford where the erection of colleges gradually
absorbed the best sites within the old walls, so that
many of the dwelling-houses are now quite two miles
from the centre of the city. The fact is attested
for Rome by the famous municipal law of Julius Cæsar,
which directs that for a mile outside the gates every
resident is to look after the repair of the road in
front of his own house.
As a general rule, the heights in
Rome were occupied by the better class of residents,
and the hollows by the lower stratum of population.
This was not indeed entirely so, for poor people no
doubt lived on the Aventine, the Caelian, and parts
of the Esquiline. But the Palatine was certainly
an aristocratic quarter; the Carinae, the height
looking down on the hollow where the Colosseum now
stands, had many good houses, e.g. those of Pompeius
and of Quintus Cicero, and we know of one man of great
wealth, Atticus, who lived on the Quirinal. It
was in the narrow hollows leading down from these
heights to the Forum, such as the Subura between
Esquiline and Quirinal, and the Argiletum farther
down near the Forum, that we meet in literature what
we may call the working classes; the Argiletum, for
example, was famous both for its booksellers and its
shoemakers, and the Subura is the typical
street of tradesmen. And no doubt the big lodging-houses
in which the lower classes dwelt were to be found
in all parts of Rome, except the strictly aristocratic
districts like the Palatine.
The whole free population may roughly
be divided into three classes, of which the first
two, constituting together the social aristocracy,
were a mere handful in number compared with the third.
At the top of the social order was the governing class,
or ordo senatorius: then came the ordo
equester, comprising all the men of business, bankers,
money-lenders, and merchants (negotiatores)
or contractors for the raising of taxes and many other
purposes (publicani). Of these two upper
classes and their social life we shall see something
in later chapters; at present we are concerned with
the “masses,” at least 320,000 in number,
and the social problems which their existence presented,
or ought to have presented, to an intelligent Roman
statesman of Cicero’s time.
Unfortunately, just as we know but
little of the populous districts of Rome, so too we
know little of its industrial population. The
upper classes, including all writers of memoirs and
history, were not interested in them. There was
no philanthropist, no devoted inquirer like Mr. Charles
Booth, to investigate their condition or try to ameliorate
it. The statesman, if he troubled himself about
them at all, looked on them as a dangerous element
of society, only to be considered as human beings
at election time; at all other times merely as animals
that had to be fed, in order to keep them from becoming
an active peril. The philosopher, even the Stoic,
whose creed was by far the most ennobling in that
age, seems to have left the dregs of the people quite
out of account; though his philosophy nominally took
the whole of mankind into its cognisance, it believed
the masses to be degraded and vicious, and made no
effort to redeem them. The Stoic might profess
the tenderest feeling towards all mankind, as Cicero
did, when moved by some recent reading of Stoic doctrine;
he might say that “men were born for the sake
of men, that each should help the other,” or
that “Nature has inclined us to love men, for
this is the foundation of all law"; but when in
actual social or political contact with the same masses
Cicero could only speak of them with contempt or disgust.
It is a melancholy and significant fact that what
little we do know from literature about this class
is derived from the part they occasionally played
in riots and revolutionary disorders. It is fortunately
quite impossible that the historian of the future
should take account of the life of the educated and
wealthy only; but in the history of the past and especially
of the last three centuries B.C., we have to contend
with this difficulty, and can only now and then find
side-lights thrown upon the great mass of mankind.
The crime, the crowding, the occasional suffering
from starvation and pestilence, in the unfashionable
quarters of such a city as Rome, these things are
hidden from us, and rarely even suggested by the histories
we commonly read.
The three questions to which I wish
to make some answer in this chapter are: (1)
how was this population housed? (2) how was it supplied
with food and clothing? and (3) how was it employed?
1. It was of course impossible
in a city like Rome that each man, married or unmarried,
should have his own house; this is not so even in
the great majority of modern industrial towns, though
we in England are accustomed to see our comparatively
well-to-do artisans dwelling in cottages spreading
out into the country. At Rome only the wealthy
families lived in separate houses (domus), about
which we shall have something to say in another chapter.
The mass of the population lived, or rather ate and
slept (for southern climates favour an out-of-door
life), in huge lodging-houses called islands (insulae),
because they were detached from other buildings, and
had streets on all sides of them, as islands have
water. These insulae were often three or
four stories high; the ground-floor was often occupied
by shops, kept perhaps by some of the lodgers, and
the upper floors by single rooms, with small windows
looking out on the street or into an interior court.
The common name for such a room was coenaculum,
or dining-room, a word which seems to be taken over
from the coenaculum of private houses, i.e.
an eating-room on the first floor, where there was
one. Once indeed we hear of an aedicula,
in an insula, which was perhaps the equivalent
of a modern “flat”; it was inhabited by
a young bachelor of good birth, M. Caelius Rufus,
the friend of Cicero, and in this case the insula
was probably one of a superior kind. The common
lodging-house must have been simply a rabbit-warren,
the crowded inhabitants using their rooms only for
eating and sleeping, while for the most part they
prowled about, either idling or getting such employment
as they could, legitimate or otherwise.
In such a life there could of course
have been no idea of home, or of that simple and sacred
family life which had once been the ethical basis
of Roman society. When we read Cicero’s thrilling
language about the loss of his own house, after his
return from exile, and then turn to think of the homeless
crowds in the rabbit-warrens of Rome, we can begin
to feel the contrast between the wealth and poverty
of that day. “What is more strictly protected,”
he says, “by all religious feeling, than the
house of each individual citizen? Here is his
altar, his hearth, here are his Di Penates:
here he keeps all the objects of his worship and performs
all his religious rites: his house is a refuge
so solemnly protected, that no one can be torn from
it by force." The warm-hearted Cicero is here,
as so often, dreaming dreams: the “each
individual citizen” of whom he speaks is the
citizen of his own acquaintance, not the vast majority,
with whom his mind does not trouble itself.
These insulae were usually built
or owned by men of capital, and were often called
by the names of their owners. Cicero, in one of
his letters, incidentally mentions that he had
money thus invested; and we are disposed to wonder
whether his insulae were kept in good repair,
for in another letter he happens to tell his man of
business that shops (tabernae) belonging to him
were tumbling down and unoccupied. It is more
than likely that many of the insulae were badly
built by speculators, and liable to collapse.
The following passage from Plutarch’s Life
of Crassus suggests this, though, if Plutarch
is right, Crassus did not build himself, but let or
sold his sites and builders to others: “Observing
(in Sulla’s time) the accidents that were familiar
at Rome, conflagrations and tumbling down of houses
owing to their weight and crowded state, he bought
slaves who were architects and builders. Having
collected these to the number of more than five hundred,
it was his practice to buy up houses on fire, and
houses next to those on fire: for the owners,
frightened and anxious, would sell them cheap.
And thus the greater part of Rome fell into the hands
of Crassus: but though he had so many artisans,
he built no house except his own, for he used to say
that those who were fond of building ruined themselves
without the help of an enemy." The fall of houses,
and their destruction in the frequent fires, became
familiar features of life at Rome about this time,
and are alluded to by Catullus in his twenty-third
poem, and later on by Strabo in his description of
Rome . It must indeed have often happened
that whole families were utterly homeless; and
in those days there were no insurance offices, no
benefit societies, no philanthropic institutions to
rescue the suffering from undeserved misery. As
we shall see later on, they were constantly in debt,
and in the hands of the money-lender; and against
his extortions their judicial remedies were most precarious.
But all this is hidden from our eyes: only now
and again we can hear a faint echo of their inarticulate
cry for help.
2. The needs of these poorer
classes in respect of food and drink were very small;
it was only the vast number of them that made the supply
difficult. The Italians, like the Greeks,
were then as now almost entirely vegetarians; cattle
and sheep were used for the production of cheese,
leather, and wool or for sacrifices to the gods; the
only animal commonly eaten, until luxury came in with
increasing wealth, was the pig, and grain and vegetables
were the staple food of the poor man, both in town
and country. Among the lesser poems ascribed to
Virgil there is one, the Moretum, which gives
a charming picture of the food-supply of the small
cultivator in the country. He rises very early,
gropes his way to the hearth, and stirs the embers
into flame: then takes from his meal-bin a supply
of grain for three days and proceeds to grind it in
a hand-mill, knead it with water, shape it into round
cakes divided into four parts like a “hot-cross
bun,” and, with the help of his one female slave,
to bake these in the embers. He has no sides
of smoked bacon, says the poet, hanging from his roof,
but only a cheese, so to add to his meal he goes into
his garden and gathers thence a number of various
herbs and vegetables, which he then makes into the
hotch-potch, or pot-au-feu which gives the name
to the poem. This bit of delicate genre-painting,
which is as good in its way as anything in Crabbe’s
homely poems, has indeed nothing to tell us of life
in an insula at Rome; but it may serve to show
what was the ordinary food of the Italian of that
day. The absence of the sides of bacon ("durati
sale terga suis,” line 57) is interesting.
No doubt the Roman took meat when he could get it;
but to have to subsist on it, even for a short time,
was painful to him, and more than once Cæsar remarks
on the endurance of his soldiers in submitting to eat
meat when corn was not to be had.
The corn which was at this time the
staple food of the Romans of the city was wheat, and
wheat of a good kind; in primitive times it had been
an inferior species called far, which survived
in Cicero’s day only in the form of cakes offered
to the gods in religious ceremonies. The wheat
was not brought from Italy or even from Latium; what
each Italian community then grew was not more than
supplied its own inhabitants, and the same was
the case with the country villas of the rich, and
the huge sheep-farms worked by slaves. By far
the greater part of Italy is mountainous, and not
well suited to the production of corn on a large scale;
and for long past other causes had combined to limit
what production there was. Transport too, whether
by road or river, was full of difficulty, while on
the other hand a glance at the map will show that
the voyage for corn-ships between Rome and Sicily,
Sardinia, or the province of Africa (the former dominion
of Carthage), was both short and easy far
shorter and easier than the voyage from Cisalpine
Gaul or even from Apulia, where the peninsula was
richest in good corn-land. So we are not surprised
to find that, according to tradition, which is fully
borne out by more certain evidence, corn had been
brought to Rome from Sicily as early as 492 B.C. to
relieve a famine, or that since Sicily, Sardinia,
and Africa had become Roman provinces, their vast productive
capacity was utilised to feed the great city.
Nor indeed need we be surprised to
find that the State has taken over the task of feeding
the Roman population, and of feeding it cheaply, if
only we are accustomed to think, not merely to read,
about life in the city at this period. Nothing
is more difficult for the ordinary reader of ancient
history than to realise the difficulty of feeding
large masses of human beings, whether crowded in towns
or soldiers in the field. Our means of transport
are now so easily and rapidly set in action and maintained,
that it would need a war with some great sea-power
to convince us that London or Glasgow might, under
certain untoward circumstances, be starved; and as
our attention has never been drawn to the details
of food-supply, we do not readily see why there should
have been any such difficulty at Rome as to call for
the intervention of the State. Perhaps the best
way to realise the problem is to reflect that every
adult inhabitant needed about four and a half pecks
of corn per month, or some three pounds a day; so that
if the population of Rome be taken at half a million
in Cicero’s time, a million and a half pounds
would be demanded as the daily consumption of the
people. I have already said that in the last three
centuries B.C. there was a universal tendency to leave
the country for the towns; and we now know that many
other cities besides Rome not only felt the same difficulty,
but actually used the same remedy State
importation of cheap corn. Even comparatively small
cities like Dyrrhachium and Apollonia in Epirus, as
Cæsar tells us while narrating his own difficulty
in feeding his army there, used for the most part
imported corn. And we must remember that while
some of the greatest cities on the Mediterranean,
such as Alexandria and Antioch, were within easy reach
of vast corn-fields, this was not the case with Rome.
Either she must organise her corn-supply on a secure
basis, or get rid of her swarms of poor inhabitants;
the latter alternative might have been possible if
she had been willing to let them starve, but probably
in no other way. To attempt to put them out upon
the land again was hopeless; they knew nothing of agriculture,
and were unused to manual labour, which they despised.
Thus ever since Rome had been a city
of any size it had been the duty of the plebeian aediles
to see that it was adequately supplied with corn,
and in times of dearth or other difficulty these magistrates
had to take special measures to procure it. With
a population steadily rising since the war with Hannibal,
and after the acquisition of two corn-growing provinces,
to which Africa was added in 146 B.C., it was natural
that they should turn their attention more closely
to the resources of these; and now the provincial
governors had to see that the necessary amount of
corn was furnished from these provinces at a fixed
price, and that a low one. In 123 B.C. Gaius
Gracchus took the matter in hand, and made it a part
of his whole far-reaching political scheme. The
plebs urbana had become a very awkward element
in the calculations of a statesman, and to have it
in a state of starvation, or even fearing such a state,
was dangerous in the extreme, as every Roman statesman
had to learn in the course of the two following centuries.
The aediles, we may guess, were quite unequal to the
work demanded of them; and at times victorious provincial
governors would bring home great quantities of corn
and give it away gratis for their private purposes,
with bad results both economic and moral. Gracchus
saw that the work of supply needed thorough organisation
in regard to production, transport, warehousing, and
finance, and set about it with a delight in hard work
such as no Roman statesman had shown before, believing
that if the people could be fed cheaply and regularly,
they would cease to be “a troublesome neighbour."
We do not know the details of his scheme of organisation
except in one particular, the price at which the corn
was to be sold per modius (peck): this
was to be six and one-third asses, or rather
less than half the normal market-price of the day,
so far as it can be made out. Whether he believed
that the cost of production could be brought down
to this level by regularity of demand and transport
we cannot tell; it seems at any rate probable that
he had gone carefully into the financial aspect of
the business. But there can hardly be a doubt
that he miscalculated, and that the result of the
law by which he sought to effect his object was a yearly
loss to the treasury, so that after his time, and until
his law was repealed by Sulla, the people were really
being fed largely at the expense of the State, and
thus lapsing into a state of semipauperism, with bad
ethical consequences.
One of these consequences was that
inconsiderate statesmen would only too readily seize
the chance of reducing the price of the corn still
lower, as was done by Saturninus in 100 B.C., for political
purposes. To prevent this Sulla abolished the
Gracchan system in toto; but it was renewed
in 73 B.C., and in 58 the demagogue P. Clodius made
the distribution of corn gratuitous. In 46 Cæsar
found that no less than 320,000 persons were receiving
corn from the State for nothing; by a bill, of which
we still possess a part, he reduced the number
to 150,000, and by a rigid system of rules, of which
we know something, contrived to ensure that it should
be kept at that point. With the policy of Augustus
and his successors in regard to the corn-supply (annona)
I am not here concerned; but it is necessary to observe
that with the establishment of the Empire the plebs
urbana ceased to be of any importance in politics,
and could be treated as a petted population, from
whom no harm was to be expected if they were kept
comfortable and amused. Augustus seems to have
found himself compelled to take up this attitude towards
them, and he was able to do so because he had thoroughly
reorganised the public finance and knew what he could
afford for the purpose. But in time of Cicero
the people were still powerful legislation and elections,
and the public finance was disorganised and in confusion;
and the result was that the corn-supply was mixed
up with politics, and handled by reckless politicians
in a way that was as ruinous to the treasury as it
was to the moral welfare of the city. The whole
story, from Gracchus onwards, is a wholesome lesson
on the mischief of granting “outdoor relief”
in any form whatever, without instituting the means
of inquiry into each individual case. Gracchus’
intentions were doubtless honest and good; but “ubi
semel recto deerratum est, in praeceps
pervenitur.”
The drink of the Roman was water,
but he mixed it with wine whenever he had the chance.
Fortunately for him he had no other intoxicating drink;
we hear neither of beer nor spirits in Roman literature.
Italy was well suited to the cultivation of the vine;
and though down to the last century of the Republic
the choice kinds of wine came chiefly from Greece,
yet we have unquestionable proof that wine was made
in the neighbourhood of Rome at the very outset of
Roman history. In the oldest religious calendar
we find two festivals called Vinalia, one in April
and the other in August; what exactly was the relation
of each of them to the operations of viticulture is
by no means clear, but we know that these operations
were under the protection of Jupiter, and that his
priest, the Flamen Dialis, offered to him
the first-fruits of the vintage. The production
of rough wine must indeed have been large, for we
happen to know that it was at times remarkably cheap.
In 250 B.C., in many ways a wonderfully productive
year, wine was sold at an as the congius,
which is nearly three quarts; under the early
Empire Columella (ii. 10) reckoned the amphora
(nearly 6 gallons) at 15 sesterces, i.e.
about eightpence That the common citizen did expect
to be able to qualify his water with wine seems proved
by a story told by Suetonius, that when the people
complained to Augustus that the price of wine was too
high, he curtly and wisely answered that Agrippa had
but lately given them an excellent water-supply.
It looks as though they were claiming to have wine
as well as grain supplied them by the government at
a low price or gratuitously; but this was too much
even for Augustus. For his water the Roman, it
need hardly be said, paid nothing. On the whole,
at the time of which we are speaking he was fairly
well supplied with it; but in this, as in so many
other matters of urban administration, it was under
Augustus that an abundant supply was first procured
and maintained by an excellent system of management.
Frontinus, to whose work de Aqueductibus we
owe almost all that we know about the Roman water-supply,
tells us that for four hundred and forty-one years
after the foundation of the city the Romans contented
themselves with such water as they could get from the
Tiber, from wells, and from natural springs, and adds
that some of the springs were in his day still held
in honour on account of their health-giving qualities.
Cicero describes Rome, in his idealising way, as “locum
fontibus abundantem,” and twenty-three springs
are known to have existed; but as early 312 B.C. it
was found necessary to seek elsewhere for a purer
and more regular supply. More than six miles
from Rome, on the via Collatina, springs were found
and utilised for this purpose, which have lately been
re-discovered at the bottom of some stone quarries;
and hence the water was brought by underground pipes
along the line of the same road to the city, and through
it to the foot of the Aventine, the plebeian quarter.
This was the Aqua Appia, named after the famous censor
Appius Claudius Caecus, whom Mommsen has
shown to have been a friend of the people. Forty
years later another censor, Manius Curius
Dentatus, brought a second supply, also by an
underground channel, from the river Anio near Tibur
(Tivoli), the water of which, never of the first quality,
was used for the irrigation of gardens and the flushing
of drains. In 144 B.C. it was found that these
two old aqueducts were out of repair and insufficient,
and this time a praetor, Q. Marcius Rex (probably
through the influence of a family clique), was commissioned
to set them in order and to procure a fresh supply.
He went much farther than his predecessors had gone
for springs, and drew a volume of excellent and clear
cold water from the Sabine hills beyond Tibur, thirty-six
miles from the city, which had the highest reputation
at all times; and for the last six miles of its course
it was carried above ground upon a series of arches.
One other aqueduct was added in 125 B.C. the Aqua
Tepula, so called because its water was unusually warm;
and the whole amount of water entering Rome in the
last century of the Republic is estimated at more
than 700,000 cubic metres per diem, which would amply
suffice for a population of half a million. At
the present day Rome, with a population of 450,000,
receives from all sources only 379,000. Baths,
both public and private, were already beginning to
come into fashion; of these more will be said later
on. The water for drinking was collected in large
castella, or reservoirs, and thence distributed
into public fountains, of which one still survives the
“Trofei di Mario,” in the Piazza
Vittorio Emmanuele on the Esquiline. When the
supply came to be large enough, the owners of insulae
and domus were allowed to have water laid on
by private pipes, as we have it in modern towns; but
it is not certain when this permission was first given.
3. But we must return to the
individual Roman of the masses, whom we have now seen
well supplied with the necessaries of life, and try
to form some idea of the way in which he was employed,
or earned a living. This is by no means an easy
task, for these small people, as we have already seen,
did not interest their educated fellow-citizens, and
for this reason we hear hardly anything of them in
the literature of the time. Not only a want of
philanthropic feeling in their betters, but an inherited
contempt for all small industry and retail dealing,
has helped to hide them away from us: an inherited
contempt, because it is in fact a survival from an
older social system, when the citizen did not need
the work of the artisan and small retailer, but supplied
all his own wants within the circle of his household,
i.e. his own family and slaves, and produced on
his farm the material of his food and clothing.
And the survival was all the stronger, because even
in the late Republic the abundant supply of slaves
enabled the man of capital still to dispense largely
with the services of the tradesman and artisan.
Cicero expresses this contempt for
the artisan and trading classes in more than one striking
passage. One, in his treatise on Duties, is probably
paraphrased from the Greek of Panaetius, the philosopher
who first introduced Stoicism to the Romans, and modified
it to suit their temperament, but it is quite clear
that Cicero himself entirely endorses the Stoic view.
“All gains made by hired labourers,” he
says, “are dishonourable and base, for what
we buy of them is their labour, not their artistic
skill: with them the very gain itself does but
increase the slavishness of the work. All retail
dealing too may be put in the same category, for the
dealer will gain nothing except by profuse lying,
and nothing is more disgraceful than untruthful huckstering.
Again, the work of all artisans (opifices) is
sordid; there can be nothing honourable in a workshop."
If this view of the low character
of the work of the artisan and retailer should be
thought too obviously a Greek one, let the reader
turn to the description by Livy a true
gentleman of the low origin of Terentius
Varro, the consul who was in command at Cannae; he
uses the same language as Cicero. “He sprang
from an origin not merely humble but sordid:
his father was a butcher, who sold his own meat, and
employed his son in this slavish business.”
The story may not be true, and indeed it is not a
very probable one, but it well represents the inherited
feeling towards retail trade of the Roman of the higher
classes of society, a feeling so tenacious
of life, that even in modern England, where it arose
from much the same causes as in the ancient world,
it has only within the last century begun to die out.
Yet in Rome these humble workers existed
and made a living for themselves from the very beginning,
as far as we can guess, of real city life. They
are the necessary and inevitable product of the growth
of a town population, and of the resulting division
of labour. The following passage from a work
on industrial organisation in England may be taken
as closely representing the same process in early
Rome: “The town arose as a centre in which
the surplus produce of many villages could be profitably
disposed of by exchange. Trade thus became a
settled occupation, and trade prepared the way for
the establishment of the handicrafts, by furnishing
capital for the support of the craftsmen, and by creating
a regular market for their products. It was possible
for a great many bodies of craftsmen, the
weavers, tailors, butchers, bakers, etc., to find
a livelihood, each craft devoting itself to the supply
of a single branch of those wants which the village
household had attempted very imperfectly to satisfy
by its own labours.”
As in mediaeval Europe, so in early
Rome, the same conditions produced the same results:
we find the craftsmen of the town forming themselves
into gilds, not only for the protection of their
trade, but from a natural instinct of association,
and providing these gilds, on the model of the older
groups of family and gens, with a religious centre
and a patron deity. The gilds (collegia)
of Roman craftsmen were attributed to Numa, like so
many other religious institutions; they included associations
of weavers, fullers, dyers, shoemakers, doctors, teachers,
painters, etc., and were mainly devoted to
Minerva as the deity of handiwork. “The
society that witnessed the coming of Minerva from
Etruria ... little knew that in her temple on the
Aventine was being brought to expression the trade-union
idea." These collegia opificum, most unfortunately,
pass entirely out of our sight, until they reappear
in the age of Cicero in a very different form, as
clubs used for political purposes, but composed still
of the lowest strata of the free population (collegia
sodalicia). The history and causes of their
disappearance and metamorphosis are lost to us; but
it is not hard to guess that the main cause is to
be found in the great economic changes that followed
the Hannibalic war, the vast number of slaves
imported, and the consequent resuscitation of the
old system of the economic independence of the great
households; the decay of religious practice, which
affected both public and private life in a hundred
different ways; and that steady growth of individualism
which is characteristic of eras of town life, and
especially of the last three centuries B.C. It
is curious to notice that by the time these old gilds
emerge into light again as clubs that could be used
for political purposes, a new source of gain, and
one that was really sordid, had been placed within
the reach of the Roman plebs urbana:
it was possible to make money by your vote in the
election of magistrates. In that degenerate when
the vast accumulation of capital made it possible
for a man to purchase his way to power, in spite of
repeated attempts to check the evil by legislation,
the old principle of honourable association was used
to help the small man to make a living by choosing
the unprincipled and often the incompetent to undertake
the government of the Empire.
Apart, however, from such illegal
means of making money, there was beyond doubt in the
Rome of the last century B.C. a large amount of honest
and useful labour done by free citizens. We must
not run away with the idea that the whole labour of
the city was performed by slaves, who ousted the freeman
from his chance of a living. There was indeed
a certain number of public slaves who did public work
for the State; but on the whole the great mass of
the servile population worked entirely within the
households and on the estates of the rich, and did
not interfere to any sensible degree with the labour
of the small freeman. As has been justly observed
by Salvioli, never at any period did the Roman
proletariat complain of the competition of slave labour
as detrimental to its own interests. Had there
been no slave labour there, the small freeman might
indeed have had a wider field of enterprise, and have
been better able to accumulate a small capital by
undertaking work for the great families, which was
done, as it was, by their slaves. But he was
not aware of this, and the two kinds of labour, the
paid and the unpaid, went on side by side without
active rivalry. No doubt slavery helped to foster
idleness, as it did in the Southern States of America
before the Civil War; no doubt there were plenty
of idle ruffians in the city, ready to steal, to murder,
or to hire themselves out as the armed followers of
a political desperado like Clodius; but the simple
necessities of the life of those who had no slaves
of their own gave employment, we may be certain, to
a great number of free tradesmen and artisans and
labourers of a more unskilled kind.
To begin with, we may ask the pertinent
question, how the corn sold cheap by the State was
made into bread for the small consumer. Pliny
gives us very valuable information, which we may accept
as roughly correct, that until the year 171 B.C. there
were no bakers in Rome. “The Quirites,”
he says, “made their own bread, which was the
business of the women, as it is still among most peoples.”
The demand which was thus supplied by a new trade
was no doubt caused by the increase of the lower population
of the city, by the return of old soldiers, often
perhaps unmarried, and by the manumission of slaves,
many of whom would also be inexperienced in domestic
life and its needs; and we may probably connect it
with the growth of the system of insulae, the
great lodging-houses in which it would not be convenient
either to grind your corn or to bake your bread.
So the bakers, called pistores from the old
practice of pounding the grain in a mortar (pingere),
soon became a very important and flourishing section
of the plebs, though never held in high repute; and
in connexion with the distributions of corn some of
them probably rose above the level of the small tradesman,
like the pistor redemptor, Marcus Vergilius
Eurysaces, whose monument has come down to us.
It should be noted that the trade of the baker included
the grinding of the corn; there were no millers at
Rome. This can be well illustrated from the numerous
bakers’ shops which have been excavated at Pompeii.
In one of these, for example, we find the four mills
in a large apartment at the rear of the building,
and close by is the stall for the donkeys that turned
them, and also the kneading-room, oven, and store-room.
Small bakeries may have had only hand-mills, like the
one with which we saw the peasant in the Moretum
grinding his corn; but the donkey was from quite early
times associated with the business, as we know from
the fact that at the festival of Vesta, the patron
deity of all bakers, they were decorated with wreaths
and cakes.
The baking trade must have given employment
to a large number of persons. So beyond doubt
did the supply of vegetables, which were brought into
the city from gardens outside, and formed, after the
corn, the staple food of the lower classes. We
have already seen in the Moretum the countryman
adding to his store of bread by a hotch-potch made
of vegetables, and the reader of the poem will have
been astonished at the number mentioned, including
garden herbs for flavouring purposes. The ancients
were fully alive to the value of vegetable food and
of fruit as a healthy diet in warm climates, and the
wonderfully full information we have on this subject
comes from medical writers like Galen, as well as
from Pliny’s Natural History, and from
the writers on agriculture. The very names of
some Roman families, e.g. the Fabii and Caepiones,
carry us back to a time when beans and onions, which
later on were not so much in favour, were a regular
part of the diet of the Roman people. The list
of vegetables and herbs which we know of as consumed
fills a whole page in Marquardt’s interesting
account of this subject, and includes most of those
which we use at the present day. It was only when
the consumption of meat and game came in with the
growth of capital and its attendant luxury, that a
vegetarian diet came to be at all despised. This
is another result of the economic changes caused by
the Hannibalic war, and is curiously illustrated by
the speech of the cook of a great household in the
Pseudolus of Plautus, who prides himself on
not being as other cooks are, who make the guests into
beasts of the field, stuffing them with all kinds
of food which cattle eat, and even with things which
cattle would refuse! we may take it that at all
times the Roman of the lower class consumed fruit and
vegetables largely, and thus gave employment to a
number of market-gardeners and small purveyors.
Fish he did not eat; like meat, it was too expensive;
in fact fish-eating only came in towards the end of
the republican period, and then only as a luxury for
those who could afford to keep fish-ponds on their
estates. How far the supply of other luxuries,
such as butchers’ meat, gave employment to freemen,
is not very clear; and perhaps we need here only take
account of such few other products, e.g. oil
and wine, as were in universal demand, though not always
procurable by the needy. There were plenty of
small shops in Rome where these things were sold;
we have a picture of such a shop (caupona)
in another of the minor Virgilian poems, the Copa,
i.e. hostess, or perhaps in this case the woman
who danced and sang for the entertainment of the guests.
She plied her trade in a smoky tavern (fumosa
taberna), all the contents of which are charmingly
described in the poem.
Let us now see how the other chief
necessity of human life, the supply of clothing, gave
employment to the free Roman shopkeeper.
The clothing of the whole Roman population
was originally woollen; both the outer garment, the
toga, the inner (tunica) were of this
material, and the sheep which supplied it were pastured
well and conveniently in all the higher hilly regions
of Italy. Other materials, linen, cotton, and
silk, came in later with the growth of commerce, but
the manufacture of these into clothing was chiefly
carried on by slaves in the great households, and we
need not take any account of them here. The preparation
of wool too was in well regulated households undertaken
even under the Empire by the women of the family,
including the materfamilias herself, and in many an
inscription we find the lanificium recorded
as the honourable practice of matrons. But as
in the case of food, so with the simple material of
clothing, it was soon found impossible in a city for
the poorer citizens to do all that was necessary within
their own houses; this is proved conclusively by the
mention of gilds of fullers (fullones)
among those traditionally ascribed to Numa. Fulling
is the preparation of cloth by cleansing in water after
it has come from the loom; but the fuller’s
trade of the later republic probably often comprised
the actual manufacture of the wool for those who could
not do it themselves. He also acted as the washer
of garments already in use, and this was no doubt
a very important part of his business, for in a warm
climate heavy woollen material is naturally apt to
get frequently impure and unwholesome. Soap was
not known till the first century of the Empire, and
the process of cleansing was all the more lengthy
and elaborate; the details of the process are known
to us from paintings at Pompeii, where they adorn
the walls of fulleries which have been excavated.
A plan of one of them will be found in Mau’s
Pompeii. The ordinary woollen
garments were simply bleached white, not dyed; and
though dyers are mentioned among the ancient gilds
by Plutarch, it is probable that he means chiefly
fullers by the Greek word [Greek: Bapheis].
Of the manufacture of leather we do
not know so much. This, like that of wool, must
have originally been carried on in the household, but
it is mentioned as a trade as early as the time of
Plautus. The shoemakers’ business was, however,
a common one from the earliest times, probably because
it needs some technical skill and experience; the
most natural division of labour in early societies
is sure to produce this trade. The shoemakers’
gild was among the earliest, and had its centre in
the atrium sutorium; and the individual
shoemakers carried on their trade in booths or shops.
The Roman shoe, it may be mentioned here, was of several
different kinds, according to the sex, rank, and occupation
of the wearer; but the two most important sorts were
the calceus, the shoe worn with the toga in
the city, and the mark of the Roman citizen; and the
pero or high boot, which was more serviceable
in the country.
Among the old gilds were also those
of the smiths (fabri ferrarii) and the potters
(figuli), but of these little need be said here,
for they were naturally fewer in number than the vendors
of food and clothing, and the raw material for their
work had, in later times at least, to be brought from
a distance. The later Romans seem to have procured
their iron-ore from the island of Elba and Spain, Gaul,
and other provinces, and to have imported ware
of all kinds, especially the finer sorts, from various
parts of the Empire; the commoner kinds, such as the
dolia or large vessels for storing wine and
oil, were certainly made in Rome in the second century
B.C., for Cato in his book on agriculture remarks
that they could be best procured there. But both
these manufactures require a certain amount of capital,
and we may doubt whether the free population was largely
employed in them; we know for certain that in the early
Empire the manufacture of ware, tiles, bricks, etc.,
was carried on by capitalists, some of them of noble
birth, including even Emperors themselves, and beyond
doubt the “hands” they employed were chiefly
slaves.
But industries of this kind may serve
to remind us of another kind of employment in which
the lower classes of Rome and Ostia may have found
the means of making a living. The importation
of raw materials, and that of goods of all kinds,
which was constantly on the increase throughout Roman
history, called for the employment of vast numbers
of porters, carriers, and what we should call dock
hands, working both at Ostia, where the heavier ships
were unladed or relieved of part of their cargoes
in order to enable them to come up the Tiber, and
also at the wharves at Rome under the Aventine.
We must also remember that almost all porterage in
the city had to be done by men, with the aid of mules
or donkeys; the streets were so narrow that in trying
to picture what they looked like we must banish from
our minds the crowds of vehicles familiar in a modern
city. Julius Cæsar, in his regulations for the
government of the city of Rome, forbade waggons to
be driven in the streets in the day-time. Even
supposing that a large amount of porterage was done
by slaves for their masters, we may reasonably guess
that free labour was also employed in this way at
Rome, as was certainly the case at Ostia, and also
at Pompeii, where the pack-carriers (saccarii)
and mule-drivers (muliones) are among the corporations
of free men who have left in the form of graffiti
appeals to voters to support a particular candidate
for election to a magistracy.
Thus we may safely conclude that there
was a very considerable amount of employment in Rome
available for the poorer citizens, quite apart from
the labour performed by slaves. But before closing
this chapter it is necessary to point out the precarious
conditions under which that employment was carried
on, as compared with the industrial conditions of
a modern city. It is true enough that the factory
system of modern times, with the sweating, the long
hours of work, and the unwholesome surroundings of
our industrial towns, has produced much misery, much
physical degeneracy; and we have also the problem of
the unemployed always with us. But there were
two points in which the condition of the free artisan
and tradesman at Rome was far worse than it is with
us, and rendered him liable to an even more hopeless
submersion than that which is too often the fate of
the modern wage-earner.
First, let us consider that markets,
then as now, were liable to fluctuation, probably
more liable then than now, because the supply both
of food and of the raw material of manufacture was
more precarious owing to the greater difficulties
of conveyance. Trade would be bad at times, and
many things might happen which would compel the man
with little or no capital to borrow money, which he
could only do on the security of his stock, or indeed,
as the law of Rome still recognised, of his person.
Money-lenders were abundant, as we shall find in the
next chapter, interest was high, and to fall into
the hands of a money-lender was only another step on
the way to destruction. At the present day, if
a tradesman fails in business, he can appeal to a
merciful bankruptcy law, which gives him every chance
to satisfy his creditors and to start afresh; or in
the case of a single debt, he can be put into a county
court where every chance is given him to pay it within
a reasonable time. All this machinery, most of
which (to the disgrace of modern civilisation) is quite
recent in date was absent at Rome. The only magistrates
administering the civil law were the praetors, and
though since the reforms of Sulla there were usually
eight of these in the city, we can well imagine how
hard it would be for the poor debtor in a huge city
to get his affairs attended to. Probably in most
cases the creditor worked his will with him, took
possession of his property without the interference
of the law, and so submerged him, or even reduced
him to slavery. If he chose to be merciful he
could go to the praetor, and get what was called a
missio in bona, i.e. a legal right to take
the whole of his debtor’s property, waiving
the right to his person. And it must be noted
that no more humane law of bankruptcy was introduced
until the time of Augustus. No wonder that at
least three times in the last century of the Republic
there arose a cry for the total abolition of debts
(tabulae novae): in 88 B.C., after the
Social War; in 63, during Cicero’s consulship,
when political and social revolutionary projects were
combined in the conspiracy of Catiline; and in 48,
when the economic condition of Italy had been disturbed
by the Civil War, and Cæsar had much difficulty in
keeping unprincipled agitators from applying violent
and foolish remedies. But to this we shall return
in the next chapter.
Secondly, let us consider that in
a large city of to-day the person and property of
all, rich or poor are adequately protected by a sound
system of police and by courts of first instance which
are sitting every day. Assault and murder, theft
and burglary, are exceptional. It might be going
too far to say that at Rome they were the rule; but
it is the fact that in what we may call the slums
of Rome there was no machinery for checking them.
No such machinery had been invented, because according
to the old rules of law, still in force, a father
might punish his children, a master his slaves, and
a murderer or thief might be killed by his intended
victim if caught red-handed. This rude justice
would suffice in a small city and a simple social
system; but it would be totally inadequate to protect
life and property in a huge population, such as that
of the Rome of the last century B.C. Since the
time of Sulla there had indeed been courts for the
trial of crimes of violence, and at all times the consuls
with their staff of assistants had been charged with
the peace of the city; but we may well ask whether
the poor Roman of Cicero’s day could really
benefit either by the consular imperium or the action
of the Sullan courts. A slave was the object
of his master’s care, and theft from a slave
was theft from his owner, if injured or
murdered satisfaction could be had for him. But
in that age of slack and sordid government it is at
least extremely doubtful whether either the person
or the property of the lower class of citizen could
be said to have been properly protected in the city.
And the same anarchy prevailed all over Italy, from
the suburbs of Rome, infested by robbers, to the sheep-farm
of the great capitalist, where the traveller might
be kidnapped by runaway slaves, to vanish from the
sight of men without leaving a trace of his fate.
It is the great merit of Augustus
that he made Rome not only a city of marble, but one
in which the person and property of all citizens were
fairly secure. By a new and rational bankruptcy
law, and by a well-organised system of police, he
made life endurable even for the poorest. If
he initiated a policy which eventually spoilt and degraded
the Roman population, if he failed to encourage free
industry as persistently as it seems to us that he
might have done, he may perhaps be in some degree
excused, as knowing the conditions and difficulties
of the problem before him better than we can know them.