All man-made wealth is subject to
inevitable decay. Aristotle said, “Labor
produces all wealth,” but the product has no
sooner left the laborer’s hands than it begins
to perish. The vital energy that produced it
must follow to preserve it from the ravages of time.
Take the life, the vital part, from
the body, and corruption begins. So with all
that has been produced, withdraw the vital force and
ruin immediately follows. The vital energy must
ever be present and active to preserve it.
Fruits and grains and provisions of
all kinds for human food rapidly perish. The
laborer must be continually active, producing and
preserving, or the race would be starving in a fortnight.
Even the miraculously bestowed manna became corrupt
in a night. It had to be gathered day by day.
Flocks and herds need the shepherd’s
care. They are subject to disease and natural
enemies and are short lived, so that however large
and strong, and healthy the herd of cattle, or the
flock of sheep, it would be soon scattered and lost
to the owner without watchful care.
Tools and instruments of production,
great or small, if used, soon need to be renewed,
or if unused perish even sooner. Neglected they
speedily decay. The locomotive left unattended
on the track would soon be utterly useless from the
destructive elements of rain and heat, frosts and
sunshine.
The palace, that floats on the ocean,
would be a prey to barnacles, to winds and waves,
to shoals and rocks, and would soon disappear, without
the constant hand of intelligent vital energy to direct
and preserve it. Houses untenanted and uncared
for soon decay. Leaks unstopped, broken windows
unrepaired, and vermin unrestrained, soon make them
unfit for habitation. Farms and plantations go
back speedily to weeds and wilderness when uncultivated.
Great cities like Babylon and Nineveh are soon so
covered with dust that we have to dig to find their
ruins.
Decay is written over every form of
man-made wealth. There is needed constantly the
touch of the laborer for its preservation.
Gold, silver and precious stones are
the least subject to decay. They are not, however,
made, but found, and simply refined and polished.
The indestructibility of silver and gold have made
them the money metals of the world, quite as much
as their rarity, their beauty and malleability.
In them wealth could be stored and moth and rust would
not corrupt.
But even gold and silver will disappear.
The thief will break through and steal. They
must be, therefore, carefully guarded. The tax
or levy of the government for its part in the protection
must be met, so that even gold and silver must also
gradually slip away.
Decay is upon all wealth and the hand
of the laborer must be ever present for its preservation.
This law is universal. Even the
Divine Creator must continue to uphold his creation.
His sustaining hand cannot be withdrawn. He must
preserve by his power and ever guide and direct, or
disorder and chaos will ensue.
Usury or interest presumes to ignore
this order of nature and demands not only that the
borrower shall resist this tendency of capital to
decay, but shall also pay a price for the privilege.
That any one should undertake to care
for and preserve the property of another without compensation
is unreasonable, but that any one should voluntarily
pay a premium for the privilege can only be explained
by misguided judgment or a perverted moral sense.
No one would be responsible for, and
care for and pay tax upon the money of another and
himself get from it no return. Trustees and administrators
receive, and feel they earn, a commission for this
caring for the property of others.
When this wealth is in the form of
a tool, or manufacturing plant, the responsibility
is greater. The owner asks that it be preserved
perfectly. There must be no decline in value,
from new improved machinery, and all accidents must
be made good; if destroyed by fire, it must be rebuilt.
To take this for a year or term of years, is a responsibility
no one would feel justified in assuming in justice
to himself. He would be using his own vital force
to preserve the perishable property of another.
A man has a farm, fertile and well
improved, and well stocked. He is to be absent
for a time. He asks as a favor that another watch
it with care, preserve the stock in condition, if
any die, replace them, and in short, so preserve that
he shall have the farm at his return, just as fertile,
the stock just as young and valuable, the implements
unworn and no signs of decay on the buildings; if any
burn, rebuild them. This would be a favor only
the kindest and weakest of neighbors or friends would
undertake, and what no man would be justified in asking
of another. This is loaning without interest and
this is the borrower, who pays only the principal
and no increase.
The usurer says, Care for my property
and pay me for the opportunity. Keep it intact.
Make good every loss and return to me an increase
which you by your energy and effort may produce.
The rates of interest greatly vary.
The average in the United States is about seven per
cent., by statistics of the government only recently
issued. At seven per cent., interest paid annually
or added to debt for ten years, the debt is doubled.
The usurer or interest taker says,
You take this hundred dollars and care for it for
me for ten years and then bring me two hundred dollars.
Take this wheat and this corn and in ten years bring
me back just twice the amount. Take these horses
and these sheep and cattle and care for them for ten
years and return them just as good as they are now,
and other horses, cattle and sheep in equal number,
which you have produced in these ten years.
Take this shop with all its tools
and implements and care for it so that in ten years
you can return it to me in as perfect order as now,
and also build me with your labor and energy another
shop, just like it, and equip it in every way just
as complete as this, and on my return give both to
me. Take this farm, fertile as it is, with its
buildings and animals and implements, and preserve
them perfectly, not a thing shall decay or decline
in value; make good every loss, and at the end of
ten years return it to me and also another farm which
you have earned during these ten years, of equal acreage
and fertility, equally improved with live stock and
implements.
The usurer gains the preservation
of his own perishable property, and he gains also
the product of the vital force of his victim.
This law of decay is a natural limitation
to the accumulation of any producer. As decay
begins at once, a part of the vital energy must be
expended in the preservation of that already produced.
As the accumulations increase, more energy is required
for its preservation, and less remains for active
production. Time does not relax his work of ruin,
and the resisting energy must be constant. The
tendency to decay is such that soon the energy required
to preserve that already gained leaves none to produce,
and the accumulations must cease.
To this point the rich fool in the
parable had come. He had abundance accumulated
and the problem was to preserve it, until he could
consume it. “This will I do, I will pull
down my barns, and build greater; and there will I
bestow all my fruits and my goods. And I will
say to my soul, Soul, thou hast much goods laid up
for many years; take thine ease, eat, drink, and be
merry.”
The usurer hands his goods to another
to build the barns and keep for him, while he is free
from its care; and, more, he requires of his victim
not only that he shall preserve, resisting all decay,
but that he shall actually pay him for the privilege.
Had the rich fool not lived in his
day, when usury was a crime, but in this age of folly,
he would have apportioned his goods among his foolisher
neighbors upon interest, to keep for him, and then
not only he, for “many years,” but his
posterity forever, could be at ease, eating, drinking,
and making merry. The silly borrowers would supply
all the needs of his endowed family, for the privilege
of caring for the goods.