THE BREAKING UP OF THE MEDIAEVAL SYSTEM
Economic Changes Of The Later Fifteenth
And The Sixteenth Centuries
36. National Affairs from
1461 to 1603. The close of the fifteenth
and the opening of the sixteenth century has been by
universal consent settled upon as the passage from
one era to another, from the Middle Ages to modern
times. This period of transition was marked in
England by at least three great movements: a
new type of intellectual life, a new ideal of government,
and the Reformation. The greatest changes in
English literature and intellectual interests are traceable
to foreign influence. In the fifteenth century
the paramount foreign influence was that of Italy.
From the middle of the fifteenth century an increasing
number of young Englishmen went to Italy to study,
and brought back with them an interest in the study
of Greek and of other subjects to which this led.
Somewhat later the social intercourse of Englishmen
with Italy exercised a corresponding influence on more
courtly literature. In 1491 the teaching of Greek
was begun at Oxford by Grocyn, and after this time
the passion for classical learning became deep, widespread,
and enthusiastic. But not only were the subjects
of intellectual interest different, but the attitude
of mind in the study of these subjects was much more
critical than it had been in the Middle Ages.
The discoveries of new routes to the far East and
of America, as well as the new speculations in natural
science which came at this time, reacted on the minds
of men and broadened their whole mental outlook.
The production of works of pure literature had suffered
a decline after the time of Wycliffe and Chaucer, from
which there was no considerable revival till the early
part of the sixteenth century. Sir Thomas More’s
Utopia, written in Latin in 1514, was a philosophical
work thrown into the form of a literary dialogue and
description of an imaginary commonwealth. But
writing became constantly more abundant and more varied
through the reigns of Henry VIII, 1509-1547, Edward
VI, 1547-1553, and Mary, 1553-1558, until it finally
blossomed out into the splendid Elizabethan literature,
just at the close of our period.
A stronger royal government had begun
with Edward IV. The conclusion of the war with
France made the king’s need for money less, and
at the same time new sources of income appeared.
Edward, therefore, from 1461, neglected to call Parliament
annually, as had been usual, and frequently allowed
three or more years to go by without any consultation
with it. He also exercised very freely what was
called the dispensing power, that is, the power to
suspend the law in certain cases, and in other ways
asserted the royal prerogative as no previous king
had done for two hundred years. But the true founder
of the almost absolute monarchy of this period was
Henry VII, who reigned from 1485 to 1509. He
was not the nearest heir to the throne, but acted
as the representative of the Lancastrian line, and
by his marriage with the lady who represented the
claim of the York family joined the two contending
factions. He was the first of the Tudor line,
his successors being his son, Henry VIII, and the three
children of Henry VIII, Edward VI, Mary, and Elizabeth.
Henry VII was an able, shrewd, far-sighted, and masterful
man. During his reign he put an end to the disorders
of the nobility; made Parliament relatively insignificant
by calling it even less frequently than Edward IV had
done, and by initiating its legislation when it did
meet. He also increased and regulated the income
of the crown, and rendered its expenditures subject
to control. He was able to keep ambassadors regularly
abroad, for the first time, and in many other ways
to support a more expensive administration, though
often by unpopular and illegal means of extortion
from the people. He formed foreign political
and commercial treaties in all directions, and encouraged
the voyages of the Cabots to America. He
brought a great deal of business constantly before
the Royal Council, but chose its members for their
ability rather than for their high rank. In these
various ways he created a strong personal government,
which left but little room for Parliament or people
to do anything except carry out his will. In
these respects Henry’s immediate successors and
their ministers followed the same policy. In
fact, the Reformation in the reign of Henry VIII,
and new internal and foreign difficulties in the reign
of Elizabeth, brought the royal power into a still
higher and more independent position.
The need for a general reformation
of the church had long been recognized. More
than one effort had been made by the ecclesiastical
authorities to insist on higher intellectual and moral
standards for the clergy and to rid the church of
various evil customs and abuses. Again, there
had been repeated efforts to clothe the king, who was
at the head of all civil government, with extensive
control and oversight of church affairs also.
Men holding different views on questions of church
government and religious belief from those held by
the general Christian church in the Middle Ages, had
written and taught and found many to agree with them.
Thus efforts to bring about changes in the established
church had not been wanting, but they had produced
no permanent result. In the early years of the
sixteenth century, however, several causes combined
to bring about a movement of this nature extending
over a number of years and profoundly affecting all
subsequent history. This is known as the Reformation.
The first steps of the Reformation in England were
taken as the result of a dispute between King Henry
VIII and the Pope. In the first place, several
laws were passed through Parliament, beginning with
the year 1529, abolishing a number of petty evils
and abusive practices in the church courts. The
Pope’s income from England was then cut off,
and his jurisdiction and all other forms of authority
in England brought to an end. Finally, the supremacy
of the king over the church and clergy and over all
ecclesiastical affairs was declared and enforced.
By the year 1535 the ancient connection between the
church in England and the Pope was severed. Thus
in England, as in many continental countries at about
the same time, a national church arose independent
of Rome. Next, changes began to be made in the
doctrine and practices of the church. The organization
under bishops was retained, though they were now appointed
by the king. Pilgrimages and the worship of saints
were forbidden, the Bible translated into English,
and other changes gradually introduced. The monastic
life came under the condemnation of the reformers.
The monasteries were therefore dissolved and their
property confiscated and sold, between the years 1536
and 1542. In the reign of Edward VI, 1547-1553,
the Reformation was carried much further. An
English prayerbook was issued which was to be used
in all religious worship, the adornments of the churches
were removed, the services made more simple, and doctrines
introduced which assimilated the church of England
to the contemporary Protestant churches on the Continent.
Queen Mary, who had been brought up
in the Roman faith, tried to make England again a
Roman Catholic country, and in the later years of her
reign encouraged severe persecutions, causing
many to be burned at the stake, in the hope of thus
crushing out heresy. After her death, however,
in 1558, Queen Elizabeth adopted a more moderate position,
and the church of England was established by law in
much the form it had possessed at the death of Henry
VIII.
In the meantime, however, there had
been growing up a far more spontaneous religious movement
than the official Reformation which has just been
described. Many thousands of persons had become
deeply interested in religion and enthusiastic in
their faith, and had come to hold different views
on church government, doctrines, and practices from
those approved of either by the Roman Catholic church
or by the government of England. Those who held
such views were known as Puritans, and throughout
the reign of Elizabeth were increasing in numbers
and making strenuous though unsuccessful efforts to
introduce changes in the established church.
The reign of Elizabeth was marked
not only by the continuance of royal despotism, by
brilliant literary production, and by the struggle
of the established church against the Catholics on
the one side and the Puritans on the other, but by
difficult and dangerous foreign relations.
More than once invasion by the continental
powers was imminent. Elizabeth was threatened
with deposition by the English adherents of Mary,
Queen of Scots, supported by France and Spain.
The English government pursued a policy of interference
in the internal conflicts of other countries that
brought it frequently to the verge of war with their
governments and sometimes beyond. Hostility bordering
on open warfare was therefore the most frequent condition
of English foreign relations. Especially was
this true of the relations with Spain. The most
serious contest with that country was the war which
culminated in the battle of the Armada in 1588.
Spain had organized an immense fleet which was intended
to go to the Netherlands and convoy an army to be
taken thence for the invasion of England. While
passing through the English Channel, a storm broke
upon them, they were attacked and harried by the English
and later by the Dutch, and the whole fleet was eventually
scattered and destroyed. The danger of invasion
was greatly reduced after this time and until the
end of Elizabeth’s reign in 1603.
37. Enclosures. The
century and a half which extends from the middle years
of the fifteenth century to the close of the sixteenth
was, as has been shown, a period remarkable for the
extent and variety of its changes in almost every
aspect of society. In the political, intellectual,
and religious world the sixteenth century seemed far
removed from the fifteenth. It is not therefore
a matter of surprise that economic changes were numerous
and fundamental, and that social organization in town
and country alike was completely transformed.
During the period last discussed,
the fourteenth and the early fifteenth century, the
manorial system had changed very considerably from
its mediaeval form. The demesne lands had been
quite generally leased to renting farmers, and a new
class of tenants was consequently becoming numerous;
serfdom had fallen into decay; the old manorial officers,
the steward, the bailiff, and the reeve had fallen
into unimportance; the manor courts were not so active,
so regular, or so numerously attended. These
changes were gradual and were still uncompleted at
the middle of the fifteenth century; but there was
already showing itself a new series of changes, affecting
still other parts of manorial life, which became steadily
more extensive during the remainder of the fifteenth
and through much of the sixteenth century. These
changes are usually grouped under the name “enclosures.”
The enclosure of land previously open
was closely connected with the increase of sheep-raising.
The older form of agriculture, grain-raising, labored
under many difficulties. The price of labor was
high, there had been no improvement in the old crude
methods of culture, nor, in the open fields and under
the customary rules, was there opportunity to introduce
any. On the other hand, the inducements to sheep-raising
were numerous. There was a steady demand at good
prices for wool, both for export, as of old, and for
the manufactures within England, which were now increasing.
Sheep-raising required fewer hands and therefore high
wages were less an obstacle, and it gave opportunity
for the investment of capital and for comparative
freedom from the restrictions of local custom.
Therefore, instead of raising sheep simply as a part
of ordinary farming, lords of manors, freeholders,
farming tenants, and even customary tenants began here
and there to raise sheep for wool as their principal
or sole production. Instances are mentioned of
five thousand, ten thousand, twenty thousand, and
even twenty-four thousand sheep in the possession
of a single person. This custom spread more and
more widely, and so attracted the attention of observers
as to be frequently mentioned in the laws and literature
of the time.
But sheep could not be raised to any
considerable extent on land divided according to the
old open field system. In a vill whose fields
all lay open, sheep must either be fed with those of
other men on the common pasture, or must be kept in
small groups by shepherds within the confines of the
various acres or other small strips of the sheep-raiser’s
holding. No large number could of course be kept
in this way, so the first thing to be done by the
sheep-raiser was to get enough strips together in
one place to make it worth while to put a hedge or
other fence around them, or else to separate off in
the same way a part or the whole of the open pastures
or meadows. This was the process known as enclosing.
Separate enclosed fields, which had existed only occasionally
in mediaeval farming, became numerous in this time,
as they have become practically universal in modern
farming in English-speaking countries.
But it was ordinarily impracticable
to obtain groups of adjacent acres or sufficiently
extensive rights on the common pasture for enclosing
without getting rid of some of the other tenants.
In this way enclosing led to evictions. Either
the lord of the manor or some one or more of the tenants
enclosed the lands which they had formerly held and
also those which were formerly occupied by some other
holders, who were evicted from their land for this
purpose.
Some of the tenants must have been
protected in their holdings by the law. As early
as 1468 Chief Justice Bryan had declared that “tenant
by the custom is as well inheritor to have his land
according to the custom as he which hath a freehold
at the common law.” Again, in 1484, another
chief justice declared that a tenant by custom who
continued to pay his service could not be ejected
by the lord of the manor. Such tenants came to
be known as copyholders, because the proof of their
customary tenure was found in the manor court rolls,
from which a copy was taken to serve as a title.
Subsequently copyhold became one of the most generally
recognized forms of land tenure in England, and gave
practically as secure title as did a freehold.
At this time, however, notwithstanding the statements
just given, the law was probably not very definite
or not very well understood, and customary tenants
may have had but little practical protection of the
law against eviction. Moreover, the great body
of the small tenants were probably no longer genuine
customary tenants. The great proportion of small
farms had probably not been inherited by a long line
of tenants, but had repeatedly gone back into the
hands of the lords of the manors and been subsequently
rented out again, with or without a lease, to farmers
or rent-paying tenants. These were in most cases
probably the tenants who were now evicted to make
room for the new enclosed sheep farms.
By these enclosures and evictions
in some cases the open lands of whole vills were enclosed,
the old agriculture came to an end, and as the enclosers
were often non-residents, the whole farming population
disappeared from the village. Since sheep-raising
required such a small number of laborers, the farm
laborers also had to leave to seek work elsewhere,
and the whole village, therefore, was deserted, the
houses fell into ruin, and the township lost its population
entirely. This was commonly spoken of at the
time as “the decaying of towns,” and those
who were responsible for it were denounced as enemies
of their country. In most cases, however, the
enclosures and depopulation were only partial.
A number of causes combined to carry this movement
forward. England was not yet a wealthy country,
but such capital as existed, especially in the towns,
was utilized and made remunerative by investment in
the newly enclosed farms and in carrying on the expenses
of enclosure. The dissolution of the monasteries
between 1536 and 1542 brought the lands which they
had formerly held into the possession of a class of
men who were anxious to make them as remunerative
as possible, and who had no feeling against enclosures.
Nevertheless, the changes were much
disapproved. Sir Thomas More condemns them in
the Utopia, as do many other writers of the
same period and of the reign of Elizabeth. The
landlords, the enclosers, the city merchants who took
up country lands, were preached against and inveighed
against by such preachers as Latimer, Lever, and Becon,
and in a dozen or more pamphlets still extant.
The government also put itself into opposition to
the changes which were in progress. It was believed
that there was danger of a reduction of the population
and thus of a lack of soldiers; it was feared that
not enough grain would be raised to provide food for
the people; the dangerous masses of wandering beggars
were partly at least recruited from the evicted tenants;
there was a great deal of discontent in the country
due to the high rents, lack of occupation, and general
dislike of change. A series of laws were therefore
carried through Parliament and other measures taken,
the object of which was to put a stop to the increase
of sheep-farming and its results. In 1488 a statute
was enacted prohibiting the turning of tillage land
into pasture. In 1514 a new law was passed reenacting
this and requiring the repair by their owners of any
houses which had fallen into decay because of the
substitution of pasture for tillage, and their reoccupation
with tenants. In 1517 a commission of investigation
into enclosures was appointed by the government.
In 1518 the Lord Chancellor, Cardinal Wolsey, issued
a proclamation requiring all those who had enclosed
lands since 1509 to throw them open again, or else
give proof that their enclosure was for the public
advantage. In 1534 the earlier laws were reenacted
and a further provision made that no person holding
rented lands should keep more than twenty-four hundred
sheep. In 1548 a new commission on enclosures
was appointed which made extensive investigations,
instituted prosecutions, and recommended new legislation.
A law for more careful enforcement was passed in 1552,
and the old laws were reenacted in 1554 and 1562.
This last law was repealed in 1593, but in 1598 others
were enacted and later extended. In 1624, however,
all the laws on the subject were repealed. As
a matter of fact, the laws seem to have been generally
ineffective. The nobility and gentry were in
the main in favor of the enclosures, as they increased
their rents even when they were not themselves the
enclosers; and it was through these classes that legislation
had to be enforced at this time if it was to be effective.
Besides the official opposition of
the government, there were occasional instances of
rioting or violent destruction of hedges and other
enclosures by the people who felt themselves aggrieved
by them. Three times these riots rose to the
height of an insurrection. In 1536 the so-called
“Pilgrimage of Grace” was a rising of the
people partly in opposition to the introduction of
the Reformation, partly in opposition to enclosures.
In 1549 a series of risings occurred, the most serious
of which was the “camp” under Kett in Norfolk,
and in 1552 again there was an insurrection in Buckinghamshire.
These risings were harshly repressed by the government.
The rural changes, therefore, progressed steadily,
notwithstanding the opposition of the law, of certain
forms of public opinion, and of the violence of mobs.
Probably enclosures more or less complete were made
during this period in as many as half the manors of
England. They were at their height in the early
years of the sixteenth century, during its latter half
they were not so numerous, and by its close the enclosing
movement had about run its course, at least for the
time.
38. Internal Divisions in
the Craft Gilds. Changes in town life
occurred during this period corresponding quite closely
to the enclosures and their results in the country.
These consisted in the decay of the gilds, the dispersion
of certain town industries through the rural districts,
and the loss of prosperity of many of the old towns.
In the earlier craft gilds each man had normally been
successively an apprentice, a journeyman, and a full
master craftsman, with a little establishment of his
own and full participation in the administration of
the fraternity. There was coming now to be a class
of artisans who remained permanently employed and never
attained to the position of master craftsmen.
This was sometimes the result of a deliberate process
of exclusion on the part of those who were already
masters. In 1480, for instance, a new set of ordinances
given to the Mercers’ Gild of Shrewsbury declares
that the fines assessed on apprentices at their entry
to be masters had been excessive and should be reduced.
Similarly, the Oxford Town Council in 1531 restricts
the payment required from any person who should come
to be a full brother of any craft in that town to
twenty shillings, a sum which would equal perhaps
fifty dollars in modern value. In the same year
Parliament forbade the collection of more than two
shillings and sixpence from any apprentice at the
time of his apprenticeship, and of more than three
shillings and fourpence when he enters the trade fully
at the expiration of his time. This indicates
that the fines previously charged must have been almost
prohibitive. In some trades the masters required
apprentices at the time of indenture to take an oath
that they would not set up independent establishments
when they had fulfilled the years of their apprenticeship,
a custom which was forbidden by Parliament in 1536.
In other cases it was no doubt the lack of sufficient
capital and enterprise which kept a large number of
artisans from ever rising above the class of journeymen.
Under these circumstances the journeymen
evidently ceased to feel that they enjoyed any benefits
from the organized crafts, for they began to form
among themselves what are generally described as “yeomen
gilds” or “journeymen gilds.”
At first the masters opposed such bodies and the city
officials supported the old companies by prohibiting
the journeymen from holding assemblies, wearing a
special livery, or otherwise acting as separate bodies.
Ultimately, however, they seem to have made good their
position, and existed in a number of different crafts
in more or less subordination to the organizations
of the masters. The first mention of such bodies
is soon after the Peasants’ Rebellion, but in
most cases the earliest rise of a journeyman gild in
any industry was in the latter part of the fifteenth
or in the sixteenth century. They were organizations
quite similar to the older bodies from which they
were a split, except that they had of course no general
control over the industry. They had, however,
meetings, officers, feasts, and charitable funds.
In addition to these functions there is reason to
believe that they made use of their organization to
influence the rate of wages and to coerce other journeymen.
Their relations to the masters’ companies were
frequently defined by regular written agreements between
the two parties. Journeymen gilds existed among
the saddlers, cordwainers, tailors, blacksmiths, carpenters,
drapers, ironmongers, founders, fishmongers, cloth-workers,
and armorers in London, among the weavers in Coventry,
the tailors in Exeter and in Bristol, the shoemakers
in Oxford, and no doubt in some other trades in these
and other towns.
Among the masters also changes were
taking place in the same direction. Instead of
all master artisans or tradesmen in any one industry
holding an equal position and taking an equal part
in the administration of affairs of the craft, there
came, at least in some of the larger companies, to
be quite distinct groups usually described as those
“of the livery” and those “not of
the livery.” The expression no doubt arose
from the former class being the more well-to-do and
active masters who had sufficient means to purchase
the suits of livery worn on state occasions, and who
in other ways were the leading and controlling members
of the organization. This came, before the close
of the fifteenth century, in many crafts to be a recognized
distinction of class or station in the company.
A statement of the members in one of the London fraternities
made in 1493 gives a good instance of this distinction
of classes, as well as of the subordinate body last
described. There were said to be at that date
in the Drapers’ Company of the craft of drapers
in the clothing, including the masters and four wardens,
one hundred and fourteen, of the brotherhood out of
the clothing one hundred and fifteen, of the bachelors’
company sixty. It was from this prominence of
the liveried gildsmen, that the term “Livery
Companies” came to be applied to the greater
London gilds. It was the wealthy merchants and
the craftsmen of the livery of the various fraternities
who rode in procession to welcome kings or ambassadors
at their entrance into the city, to add lustre to
royal wedding ceremonies, or give dignity to other
state occasions. In 1483 four hundred and six
members of livery companies riding in mulberry colored
coats attended the coronation procession of Richard
III. The mayors and sheriffs and aldermen of London
were almost always livery men in one or another of
the companies. A substantial fee had usually
to be paid when a member was chosen into the livery,
which again indicates that they were the wealthier
members. Those of the livery controlled the policy
of the gild to the exclusion of the less conspicuous
members, even though these were also independent masters
with journeymen and apprentices of their own.
But the practical administration of
the affairs of the wealthier companies came in many
cases to be in the hands of a still smaller group
of members. This group was often known as the
“Court of Assistants,” and consisted of
some twelve, twenty, or more members who possessed
higher rights than the others, and, with the wardens
or other officials, decided disputes, negotiated with
the government or other authorities, disposed of the
funds, and in other ways governed the organized craft
or trade. At a general meeting of the members
of the Mercers of London, for instance, on July 23,
1463, the following resolution was passed: “It
is accorded that for the holding of many courts and
congregations of the fellowship, it is odious and grievous
to the body of the fellowship and specially for matters
of no great effect, that hereafter yearly shall be
chosen and associated to the wardens for the time
being twelve other sufficient persons to be assistants
to the said wardens, and all matters by them finished
to be holden firm and stable, and the fellowship to
abide by them.” Sixteen years later these
assistants with the wardens were given the right to
elect their successors.
Thus before the close of the sixteenth
century the craft and trading organizations had gone
through a very considerable internal change. In
the fourteenth century they had been bodies of masters
of approximately equal position, in which the journeymen
participated in some of the elements of membership,
and would for the most part in due time become masters
and full members. Now the journeymen had become
for the most part a separate class, without prospect
of mastership. Among the masters themselves a
distinct division between the more and the less wealthy
had taken place, and an aristocratic form of government
had grown up which put the practical control of each
of the companies in the hands of a comparatively small,
self-perpetuating ruling body. These developments
were all more marked, possibly some of them were only
true, in the case of the London companies. London,
also, so far as known, is the only English town in
which the companies were divided into two classes,
the twelve “Greater Companies,” and the
fifty or more “Lesser Companies”; the former
having practical control of the government of the
city, the latter having no such influence.
39. Change of Location of
Industries. The changes described above
were, as has been said, the result of development from
within the craft and trading organizations themselves,
resulting probably in the main from increasing wealth.
There were other contemporary changes in these companies
which were rather the result of external influences.
One of these external factors was the old difficulty
which arose from artisans and traders who were not
members of the organized companies. There had
always been men who had carried on work surreptitiously
outside of the limits of the authorized organizations
of their respective industries. They had done
this from inability or unwillingness to conform to
the requirements of gild membership, or from a desire
to obtain more employment by underbidding in price,
or additional profit by using unapproved materials
or methods. Most of the bodies of ordinances
mention such workmen and traders, men who have not
gone through a regular apprenticeship, “foreigners”
who have come in from some other locality and are
not freemen of the city where they wish to work, irresponsible
men who will not conform to the established rules
of the trade. This class of persons was becoming
more numerous through the fifteenth and sixteenth centuries,
notwithstanding the efforts of the gilds, supported
by municipal and national authority. The prohibition
of any workers setting up business in a town unless
they had previously obtained the approval of the officials
of their trade was more and more vigorous in the later
ordinances; the fines imposed upon masters who engaged
journeymen who had not paid the dues, newcomers into
the town, were higher. The complaints of the
intrusion of outsiders were more loud and frequent.
There was evidently more unsupervised, unregulated
labor.
But the increase in the number of
these unorganized laborers, these craftsmen and traders
not under the control of the gilds, was most marked
in the rural districts, that is to say, in market towns
and in villages entirely outside of the old manufacturing
and trading centres. Even in the fourteenth century
there were a number of weavers, and probably of other
craftsmen, who worked in the villages in the vicinity
of the larger towns, such as London, Norwich, and
York, and took their products to be sold on fair or
market days in these towns. But toward the end
of the fifteenth century this rural labor received
a new kind of encouragement and a corresponding extension
far beyond anything before existing. The English
cloth-making industry at this period was increasing
rapidly. Whereas during the earlier periods,
as we have seen, wool was the greatest of English
exports, now it was coming to be manufactured within
the country. In connection with this manufacture
a new kind of industrial organization began to show
itself which, when it was completed, became known
as the “domestic system.” A class
of merchants or manufacturers arose who are spoken
of as “clothiers,” or “merchant
clothiers,” who bought the wool or other raw
material, and gave it out to carders or combers, spinners,
weavers, fullers, and other craftsmen, paying them
for their respective parts in the process of manufacture,
and themselves disposing of the product at home or
for export. The clothiers were in this way a
new class of employers, putting the master weavers
or other craftsmen to work for wages. The latter
still had their journeymen and apprentices, but the
initiative in their industry was taken by the merchants,
who provided the raw material and much of the money
capital, and took charge of the sale of the completed
goods. The craftsmen who were employed in this
form of industry did not usually dwell in the old
populous and wealthy towns. It is probable that
the restrictions of the gild ordinances were disadvantageous
both to the clothiers and to the small master craftsmen,
and that the latter, as well as journeymen who had
no chance to obtain an independent position, now that
the town craft organizations were under the control
of the more wealthy members, were very ready to migrate
to rural villages. Thus, in as far as the weaving
industry was growing up under the management of the
employing clothiers, it was slipping out from under
the control of the town gilds by its location in the
country. The same thing occurred in other cases,
even without the intermediation of a new employing
class. We hear of mattress makers, of rope makers,
of tile makers, and other artisans establishing themselves
in the country villages outside of the towns, where,
as a law of 1495 says, “the wardens have no power
or authority to make search.” In certain
parts of England, in the southwest, the west, and
the northwest, independent weavers now set up for
themselves in rural districts as those of the eastern
counties had long done, buying their own raw materials,
bringing their manufactures to completion, and then
taking them to the neighboring towns and markets to
sell, or hawking them through the rural districts.
These changes, along with others occurring
simultaneously, led to a considerable diminution of
the prosperity of many of the large towns. They
were not able to pay their usual share of taxation,
the population of some of them declined, whole streets
or quarters, when destroyed by fire or other catastrophe,
were left unbuilt and in ruins. Many of the largest
and oldest towns of England are mentioned in the statutes
of the reign of Henry VIII as being more or less depleted
in population. The laws and literature of the
time are ringing with complaints of the “decay
of the towns,” where the reference is to cities,
as well as where it is to rural villages. Certain
new towns, it is true, were rising into greater importance,
and certain rural districts were becoming populous
with this body of artisans whose living was made partly
by their handicraft, partly by small farming.
Nevertheless the old city craft organizations were
permanently weakened and impoverished by thus losing
control of such a large proportion of their various
industries. The occupations which were carried
on in the country were pursued without supervision
by the gilds. They retained control only of that
part of industry which was still carried on in the
towns.
40. The Influence of the Government
on the Gilds. Internal divisions and
external changes in the distribution of industry were
therefore alike tending to weaken the gild organization.
It had to suffer also from the hostility or intrusion
of the national government. Much of the policy
of the government tended, it is true, as in the case
of the enclosures, to check the changes in progress,
and thus to protect the gild system. It has been
seen that laws were passed to prohibit the exclusion
of apprentices and journeymen from full membership
in the crafts. As early as 1464 a law was passed
to regulate the growing system of employment of craftsmen
by clothiers. This was carried further in a law
of 1511, and further still in 1551 and 1555. The
manufacture of rope in the country parts of Dorsetshire
was prohibited and restricted to the town of Bridport
in 1529; the cloth manufacture which was growing up
through the “hamlets, thorps, and villages”
in Worcestershire was forbidden in 1553 to be carried
on except in the five old towns of Worcester, Evesham,
Droitwich, Kidderminster, and Bromsgrove; in 1543
it was enacted that coverlets were not to be manufactured
in Yorkshire outside of the city of York, and there
was still further legislation in the same direction.
Numerous acts were also passed for the purpose of
restoring the populousness of the towns. There
is, however, little reason to believe that these laws
had much more effect in preventing the narrowing of
the control of the gilds and the scattering of industries
from the towns to the country than the various laws
against enclosures had, and the latter object was
practically surrendered by the numerous exceptions
to it in laws passed in 1557, 1558, and 1575.
All the laws favoring the older towns were finally
repealed in 1623.
Another class of laws may seem to
have favored the craft organizations. These were
the laws regulating the carrying on of various industries,
in some of which the enforcement of the laws was intrusted
to the gild authorities. The statute book during
the sixteenth century is filled with laws “for
the true making of pins,” “for the making
of friezes and cottons in Wales,” “for
the true currying of leather,” “for the
making of iron gads,” “for setting prices
on wines,” for the regulation of the coopers,
the tanners, the makers of woollen cloth, the dyers,
the tallow chandlers, the saddlers and girdlers, and
dozens of other occupations. But although in many
of these laws the wardens of the appropriate crafts
are given authority to carry out the requirements
of the statute, either of themselves or along with
the town officials or the justices of the peace; yet,
after all, it is the rules established by government
that they are to carry out, not their own rules, and
in many of the statutes the craft authorities are
entirely ignored. This is especially true of the
“Statute of Apprentices,” passed in the
fifth year of the reign of Queen Elizabeth, 1563.
This great industrial code, which remained on the
statute book for two hundred and fifty years, being
repealed only in 1813, was primarily a reenactment
of the statutes of laborers, which had been continued
from time to time ever since their introduction in
1349. It made labor compulsory and imposed on
the justices of the peace the duty of meeting in each
locality once a year to establish wages for each kind
of industry. It required a seven years’
apprenticeship for every person who should engage in
any trade; established a working day of twelve hours
in summer and during daylight in winter; and enacted
that all engagements, except those for piece work,
should be by the year, with six months’ notice
of a close of the contract by either employer or employee.
By this statute all the relations between master and
journeyman and the rules of apprenticeship were regulated
by the government instead of by the individual craft
gilds. It is evident that the old trade organizations
were being superseded in much of their work by the
national government. Freedom of action was also
restricted by the same power in other respects also.
As early as 1436 a law had been passed, declaring
that the ordinances made by the gilds were in many
cases unreasonable and injurious, requiring them to
submit their existing ordinances to the justices at
Westminster, and prohibiting them from issuing any
new ones until they had received the approval of these
officials. There is no indication of the enforcement
of this law. In 1504, however, it was reenacted
with the modification that approval might be sought
from the justices on circuit. In 1530 the same
requirement was again included in the law already referred
to prohibiting excessive entrance fees. As the
independent legislation of the gilds for their industries
was already much restricted by the town governments,
their remaining power to make rules for themselves
must now have been very slight. Their power of
jurisdiction was likewise limited by a law passed
in 1504, prohibiting the companies from making any
rule forbidding their members to appeal to the ordinary
national courts in trade disputes.
But the heaviest blow to the gilds
on the part of the government came in 1547, as a result
of the Reformation. Both the organizations formed
for the control of the various industries, the craft
gilds, social, or religious gilds,
had property in their possession which had been bequeathed
or given to them by members on condition that the gild
would always support or help to support a priest, should
see that mass was celebrated for the soul of the donor
and his family, should keep a light always burning
before a certain shrine, or for other religious objects.
These objects were generally looked upon as superstitious
by the reformers who became influential under Edward
VI, and in the first year of his reign a statute was
passed which confiscated to the crown, to be used
for educational or other purposes, all the properly
of every kind of the purely religious and social gilds,
and that part of the property of the craft gilds which
was employed by them for religious purposes.
One of the oldest forms of voluntary organization
in England therefore came to an end altogether, and
one of the strongest bonds which had held the members
of the craft gilds together as social bodies was removed.
After this time the companies had no religious functions,
and were besides deprived of a considerable proportion
of their wealth. This blow fell, moreover, just
at a time when all the economic influences were tending
toward their weakening or actual disintegration.
The trade and craft companies of London,
like those of other towns, were called upon at first
to pay over to the government annually the amount
which they had before used for religious purposes.
Three years after the confiscation they were required
to pay a lump sum representing the capitalized value
of this amount, estimated for the London companies
at L20,000. In order to do so they were of course
forced to sell or mortgage much of their land.
That which they succeeded in retaining, however, or
bought subsequently was relieved of all government
charges, and being situated for the most part in the
heart of London, ultimately became extremely valuable
and is still in their possession. So far have
the London companies, however, departed from their
original purpose that their members have long ceased
to have any connection with the occupations from which
the bodies take their names.
41. General Causes and Evidences
of the Decay of the Gilds. An analogous
narrowing of the interests of the crafts occurred in
the form of a cessation of the mystery plays.
Dramatic shows continued to be brought out yearly
by the crafts in many towns well into the sixteenth
century. It is to be noticed, however, that this
was no longer done spontaneously. The town governments
insisted that the pageants should be provided as of
old, and on the approach of Corpus Christi day, or
whatever festival was so celebrated in the particular
town, instructions were given for their production,
pecuniary help being sometimes provided to assist
the companies in their expense. The profit which
came to the town from the influx of visitors to see
the pageants was a great inducement to the town government
to insist on their continuance. On the other
hand, the competition of dramas played by professional
actors tended no doubt to hasten the effect of the
impoverishment and loss of vitality of the gilds.
In the last half of the sixteenth century the mystery
plays seem to have come finally to an end.
Thus the gilds lost the unity of their
membership, were weakened by the growth of industry
outside of their sphere of control, superseded by
the government in many of their economic functions,
deprived of their administrative, legislative, and
jurisdictional freedom, robbed of their religious
duties and of the property which had enabled them
to fulfil them, and no longer possessed even the bond
of their dramatic interests. So the fraternities
which had embodied so much of the life of the people
of the towns during the thirteenth, fourteenth, and
fifteenth centuries now came to include within their
organization fewer and fewer persons and to affect
a smaller and smaller part of their interests.
Although the companies continued to exist into later
times, yet long before the close of the period included
in this chapter they had become relatively inconspicuous
and insignificant.
One striking evidence of their diminished
strength, and apparently a last effort to keep the
gild organization in existence, is the curious combination
or consolidation of the companies under the influence
of the city governments. Numerous instances of
the combination of several trades are to be found
in the records of every town, as for instance the
“company of goldsmiths and smiths and others
their brethren,” at Hull in 1598, which consisted
of goldsmiths, smiths, pewterers, plumbers and glaziers,
painters, cutlers, musicians, stationers and bookbinders,
and basket-makers. A more striking instance is
to be found in Ipswich in 1576, where the various
occupations were all drawn up into four companies,
as follows: (1) The Mercers; including the mariners,
shipwrights, bookbinders, printers, fishmongers, sword-setters,
cooks, fletchers, arrowhead-makers, physicians, hatters,
cappers, mercers, merchants, and several others. (2)
The Drapers; including the joiners, carpenters, innholders,
freemasons, bricklayers, tilers, carriers, casket-makers,
surgeons, clothiers, and some others. (3) The Tailors;
including the cutlers, smiths, barbers, chandlers,
pewterers, minstrels, peddlers, plumbers, pinners,
millers, millwrights, coopers, shearmen, glaziers,
turners, tinkers, tailors, and others. (4) The Shoemakers;
including the curriers, collar-makers, saddlers, pointers,
cobblers, skinners, tanners, butchers, carters, and
laborers. Each of these four companies was to
have an alderman and two wardens, and all outsiders
who came to the town and wished to set up trade were
to be placed by the town officials in one or the other
of the four companies. The basis of union in some
of these combinations was evidently the similarity
of their occupations, as the various workers in leather
among the “Shoemakers.” In other cases
there is no such similarity, and the only foundation
that can be surmised for the particular grouping is
the contiguity of the streets where the greatest number
of particular artisans lived, or their proportionate
wealth. Later, this process reached its culmination
in such a case as that of Preston in 1628, where all
the tradesmen of the town were organized as one company
or fraternity called “The Wardens and Company
of Drapers, Mercers, Grocers, Salters, Ironmongers,
and Haberdashers.” The craft and trading
gilds in their mediaeval character had evidently come
to an end.
42. The Growth of Native Commerce. The
most distinctive characteristic of English foreign
trade down to the middle of the fifteenth century
consisted in the fact that it had been entirely in
the hands of foreigners. The period under discussion
saw it transferred with quite as great completeness
to the hands of Englishmen. Even before 1450
trading vessels had occasionally been sent out from
the English seaport towns on more or less extensive
voyages, carrying out English goods, and bringing back
those of other countries or of other parts of England.
These vessels sometimes belonged to the town governments,
sometimes to individual merchants. This kind
of enterprise became more and more common. Individual
merchants grew famous for the number and size of their
ships and the extent of their trade; as for instance,
William Canynges of Bristol, who in 1461 had ten vessels
at sea, or Sturmys of the same town, who at about
the same time sent the first English vessel to trade
with the eastern Mediterranean, or John Taverner of
Hull, who built in 1449 a new type of vessel modelled
on the carracks of Genoa and the galleys of Venice.
In the middle of the fourteenth century the longest
list of merchants of any substance that could be drawn
up contained only 169 names. At the beginning
of the sixteenth century there were at least 3000
merchants engaged in foreign trade, and in 1601 there
were about 3500 trading to the Netherlands alone.
These merchants exported the old articles of English
production and to a still greater extent textile goods,
the manufacture of which was growing so rapidly in
England. The export of wool came to an end during
the reign of Queen Elizabeth, but the export of woven
cloth was more than enough to take its place.
There was not so much cloth now imported, but a much
greater variety and quantity of food-stuffs and wines,
of articles of fine manufacture, and of the special
products of the countries to which English trade extended.
The entrance of English vessels into
ports of towns or countries whose own vessels had
been accustomed to the control of the trade with England,
or where the old commercial towns of the Hanseatic
League, of Flanders, or of Italy had valuable trading
concessions, was not obtained without difficulty,
and there was a constant succession of conflicts more
or less violent, and of disputes between English and
foreign sailors and merchants. The progress of
English commerce was, however, facilitated by the
decay in the prosperity of many of these older trading
towns. The growth of strong governments in Denmark,
Sweden, Norway, Poland, and Russia resulted in a withdrawal
of privileges which the Hanseatic League had long
possessed, and internal dissensions made the League
very much weaker in the later fifteenth century than
it had been during the century and a half before.
The most important single occurrence showing this
tendency was the capture of Novgorod by the Russian
Czar and his expulsion of the merchants of the Hanse
from their settlement in that commercial centre.
In the same way most of the towns along the south
coast of the Baltic came under the control of the
kingdom of Poland.
A similar change came about in Flanders,
where the semi-independent towns came under the control
of the dukes of Burgundy. These sovereigns had
political interests too extensive to be subordinated
to the trade interests of individual towns in their
dominions. Thus it was that Bruges now lost much
of its prosperity, while Antwerp became one of the
greatest commercial cities of Europe. Trading
rights could now be obtained from centralized governments,
and were not dependent on the interest or the antagonism
of local merchants.
In Italy other influences were leading
to much the same results. The advance of Turkish
conquests was gradually increasing the difficulties
of the Eastern trade, and the discovery of the route
around the Cape of Good Hope in 1498 finally diverted
that branch of commerce into new lines. English
merchants gained access to some of this new Eastern
trade through their connection with Portugal, a country
advantageously situated to inherit the former trade
of Italy and southern Germany. English commerce
also profited by the predominance which Florence obtained
over Pisa, Genoa, and other trading towns. Thus
conditions on the Continent were strikingly favorable
to the growing commercial enterprise of England.
43. The Merchants Adventurers. English
merchants who exported and imported goods in their
own vessels were, with the exception of the staplers
or exporters of wool and other staple articles, usually
spoken of as “adventurers,” “venturers,”
or “merchants adventurers.” This
term is used in three different senses. Sometimes
it simply means merchants who entered upon adventure
or risk by sending their goods outside of the country
to new or unrecognized markets, as the “adventurers
to Iceland,” “adventurers to Spain.”
Again, it is applied to groups of merchants in various
towns who were organized for mutual protection or
other advantage, as the “fishmongers adventurers”
who brought their complaints before the Royal Council
in 1542, “The Master, Wardens, and Commonalty
of Merchant Venturers, of Bristol,” existing
apparently in the fourteenth century, fully organized
by 1467, and incorporated in 1552, “The Society
of Merchants Adventurers of Newcastle upon Tyne,”
or the similar bodies at York and Exeter.
But by far the most frequent use of
the term is that by which it was applied to those
merchants who traded to the Netherlands and adjacent
countries, especially as exporters of cloth, and who
came within this period to be recognized and incorporated
as the “Merchants Adventurers” in a special
sense, with headquarters abroad, a coat of arms of
their own, extensive privileges, great wealth, influence,
and prominence. These English merchants, trading
to the Netherlands in other articles than those controlled
by the Staplers, apparently received privileges of
trade from the duke of Brabant as early as the thirteenth
century, and the right of settling their own disputes
before their own “consul” in the fourteenth.
But their commercial enterprises must have been quite
insignificant, and it was only during the fifteenth
century that they became numerous and their trade in
English cloth extensive. Just at the beginning
of this century, in 1407, the king of England gave
a general charter to all merchants trading beyond
seas to assemble in definite places and choose for
themselves consuls or governors to arrange for their
common trade advantage. After this time, certainly
by the middle of the century, the regular series of
governors of the English merchants in the Netherlands
was established, one of the earliest being William
Caxton, afterward the founder of printing in England.
On the basis of these concessions and of the privileges
and charters granted by the home government the “Merchants
Adventurers” gradually became a distinct organization,
with a definite membership which was obtained by payment
of a sum which gradually rose from 6_s._ 8_d._ to L20,
until it was reduced by a law of Parliament in 1497
to L6 13_s._ 4_d._ They had local branches in England
and on the Continent. In 1498 they were granted
a coat of arms by Henry VII, and in 1503 by royal charter
a distinct form of government under a governor and
twenty-four assistants. In 1564 they were incorporated
by a royal charter by the title of “The Merchants
Adventurers of England.” Long before that
time they had become by far the largest and most influential
company of English exporting merchants. It is
said that the Merchants Adventurers furnished ten
out of the sixteen London ships sent to join the fleet
against the Armada.
Most of their members were London
mercers, though there were also in the society members
of other London companies, and traders whose homes
were in other English towns than London. The meetings
of the company in London were held for a long while
in the Mercers’ hall, and their records were
kept in the same minute book as those of the Mercers
until 1526. On the Continent their principal office,
hall, or gathering place, the residence of their Governor
and location of the “Court,”, or central
government of the company, was at different times
at Antwerp, Bruges, Calais, Hamburg, Stade, Groningen
and Middleburg; for the longest time probably at the
first of these places. The larger part of the
foreign trade of England during the fifteenth and most
of the sixteenth century was carried on and extended
as well as controlled and regulated by this great
commercial company.
During the latter half of the sixteenth
century, however, other companies of merchants were
formed to trade with various countries, most of them
receiving a government charter and patronage.
Of these the Russia or Muscovy Company obtained recognition
from the government in 1554, and in 1557, when an
ambassador from that country came to London, a hundred
and fifty merchants trading to Russia received him
in state. In 1581 the Levant or Turkey Company
was formed, and its members carried their merchandise
as far as the Persian Gulf. In 1585 the Barbary
or Morocco Company was formed, but seems to have failed.
In 1588, however, a Guinea Company began trading, and
in 1600 the greatest of all, the East India Company,
was chartered. The expeditions sent out by the
Bristol merchants and then by the king under the Cabots,
those other voyages so full of romance in search of
a northwest or a northeast passage to the Orient, and
the no less adventurous efforts to gain entrance to
the Spanish possessions in the west, were a part of
the same effort of commercial companies or interests
to carry their trading into new lands.
44. Government Encouragement
of Commerce. Before the accession of
Henry VII it is almost impossible to discover any deliberate
or continuous policy of the government in commercial
matters. From this time forward, however, through
the whole period of the Tudor monarchs a tolerably
consistent plan was followed of favoring English merchants
and placing burdens and restrictions upon foreign traders.
The merchants from the Hanse towns, with their
dwellings, warehouses, and offices at the Steelyard
in London, were subjected to a narrower interpretation
of the privileges which they possessed by old and
frequently renewed grants. In 1493 English customs
officers began to intrude upon their property; in
1504 especially heavy penalties were threatened if
they should send any cloth to the Netherlands during
the war between the king and the duke of Burgundy.
During the reign of Henry VIII the position of the
Hansards was on the whole easier, but in 1551 their
special privileges were taken away, and they were put
in the same position as all other foreigners.
There was a partial regrant of advantageous conditions
in the early part of the reign of Elizabeth, but finally,
in 1578, they lost their privileges forever.
As a matter of fact, German traders now came more and
more rarely to England, and their settlement above
London Bridge was practically deserted.
The fleet from Venice also came less
and less frequently. Under Henry VIII for a period
of nine years no fleet came to English ports; then
after an expedition had been sent out from Venice in
1517, and again in 1521, another nine years passed
by. The fleet came again in 1531, 1532, and 1533,
and even afterward from time to time occasional private
Venetian vessels came, till a group of them suffered
shipwreck on the southern coast in 1587, after which
the Venetian flag disappeared entirely from those
waters.
In the meantime a series of favorable
commercial treaties were made in various directions
by Henry VII and his successors. In 1490 he made
a treaty with the king of Denmark by which English
merchants obtained liberty to trade in that country,
in Norway, and in Iceland. Within the same year
a similar treaty was made with Florence, by which the
English merchants obtained a monopoly of the sale of
wool in the Florentine dominions, and the right to
have an organization of their own there, which should
settle trade disputes among themselves, or share in
the settlement of their disputes with foreigners.
In 1496 the old trading relations with the Netherlands
were reestablished on a firmer basis than ever by
the treaty which has come in later times to be known
as the Intercursus Magnus. In the same
year commercial advantages were obtained from France,
and in 1499 from Spain. Few opportunities were
missed by the government during this period to try
to secure favorable conditions for the growing English
trade. Closely connected as commercial policy
necessarily was with political questions, the former
was always a matter of interest to the government,
and in all the ups and downs of the relations of England
with the Continental countries during the sixteenth
century the foothold gained by English merchants was
always preserved or regained after a temporary loss.
The closely related question of English
ship-building was also a matter of government encouragement.
In 1485 a law was passed declaring that wines of the
duchies of Guienne and Gascony should be imported
only in vessels which were English property and manned
for the most part by Englishmen. In 1489 woad,
a dyestuff from southern France, was included, and
it was ordered that merchandise to be exported from
England or imported into England should never be shipped
in foreign vessels if sufficient English vessels were
in the harbor at the time. Although this policy
was abandoned during the short reign of Edward VI
it was renewed and made permanent under Elizabeth.
By indirect means also, as by the encouragement of
fisheries, English seafaring was increased.
As a result of these various forms
of commercial influence, the enterprise of individual
English merchants, the formation of trading companies,
the assistance given by the government through commercial
treaties and favoring statutes, English commerce became
vastly greater than it had ever been before, reaching
to Scandinavia and Russia, to Germany and the Netherlands,
to France and Spain, to Italy and the eastern Mediterranean,
and even occasionally to America. Moreover, it
had come almost entirely into the hands of Englishmen;
and the goods exported and imported were carried for
the most part in ships of English build and ownership,
manned by English sailors.
45. The Currency. The
changes just described were closely connected with
contemporary changes in the gold and silver currency.
Shillings were coined for the first time in the reign
of Henry VII, a pound weight of standard silver being
coined into 37 shillings and 6 pence. In 1527
Henry VIII had the same amount of metal coined into
40 shillings, and later in the year, into 45 shillings.
In 1543 coin silver was changed from the old standard
of 11 ounces 2 pennyweights of pure silver to 18 pennyweights
of alloy, so as to consist of 10 ounces of silver
to 2 ounces of alloy; and this was coined into 48
shillings. In 1545 the coin metal was made one-half
silver, one-half alloy; in 1546, one-third silver,
two-thirds alloy; and in 1550, one-fourth silver,
three-fourths alloy. The gold coinage was correspondingly
though not so excessively debased. The lowest
point of debasement for both silver and gold was reached
in 1551. In 1560 Queen Elizabeth began the work
of restoring the currency to something like its old
standard. The debased money was brought to the
mints, where the government paid the value of the
pure silver in it. Money of a high standard and
permanently established weight was then issued in
its place. Much of the confusion and distress
prevalent during the reigns of Henry VIII and Edward
VI was doubtless due to this selfish and unwise monetary
policy.
At about the same time a new influence
on the national currency came into existence.
Strenuous but not very successful efforts had long
been made to draw bullion into England and prevent
English money from being taken out. Now some
of the silver and gold which was being extorted from
the natives and extracted from the mines of Mexico
and Peru by the Spaniards began to make its way into
England, as into other countries of Europe. These
American sources of supply became productive by about
1525, but very little of this came into general European
circulation or reached England till the middle of the
century. After about 1560, however, through trade,
and sometimes by even more direct routes, the amount
of gold and silver money in circulation in England
increased enormously. No reliable statistics
exist, but there can be little doubt that the amount
of money in England, as in Europe at large, was doubled,
trebled, quadrupled, or perhaps increased still more
largely within the next one hundred years.
This increase of money produced many
effects. One of the most important was its effect
on prices. These had begun to rise in the early
part of the century, principally as a result of the
debasement of the coinage. In the latter part
of the century the rise was much greater, due now,
no doubt, to the influx of new money. Most commodities
cost quite four times as much at the end of the sixteenth
century as they did at its beginning.
Another effect of the increased amount
of currency appeared in the greater ease with which
the use of money capital was obtained. Saving
up and borrowing were both more practicable. More
capital was now in existence and more persons could
obtain the use of it. As a result, manufacturing,
trade, and even agriculture could now be conducted
on a more extensive scale, changes could be introduced,
and production was apt to be profitable, as prices
were increasing and returns would be greater even
than those calculated upon.
46. Interest. Any
extensive and varied use of capital is closely connected
with the payment of interest. In accord with a
strict interpretation of certain passages in both
the Old and the New Testament, the Middle Ages regarded
the payment of interest for the use of money as wicked.
Interest was the same as usury and was illegal.
As a matter of fact, most regular occupations in the
Middle Ages required very little capital, and this
was usually owned by the agriculturists, handicraftsmen,
or merchants themselves; so that borrowing was only
necessary for personal expenses or in occasional exigencies.
With the enclosures, sheep farming, consolidation of
farms, and other changes in agriculture, with the beginning
of manufacturing under the control of capitalist manufacturers,
with the more extensive foreign trading and ship owning,
and above all with the increase in the actual amount
of money in existence, these circumstances were changed.
It seemed natural that money which one person had
in his possession, but for which he had no immediate
use, should be loaned to another who could use it
for his own enterprises. These enterprises might
be useful to the community, advantageous to himself,
and yet profitable enough to allow him to pay interest
for the use of the money to the capitalist who loaned
it to him. As a matter of fact much money was
loaned and, legally or illegally, interest or usury
was paid for it. Moreover, a change had been going
on in legal opinion parallel to these economic changes,
and in 1545 a law was passed practically legalizing
interest if it was not at a higher rate than ten per
cent. This was, however, strongly opposed by
the religious opinion of the time, especially among
men of Puritan tendencies. They seemed, indeed,
to be partially justified by the fact that the control
of capital was used by the rich men of the time in
such a way as to cause great hardship. In 1552,
therefore, the law of 1545 was repealed, and interest,
except in the few forms in which it had always been
allowed, was again prohibited. But the tide soon
turned, and in 1571 interest up to ten per cent was
again made lawful. From that time forward the
term usury was restricted to excessive interest, and
this alone was prohibited. Yet the practice of
receiving interest for the loan of money was still
generally condemned by writers on morals till quite
the end of this period; though lawyers, merchants,
and popular opinion no longer disapproved of it if
the rate was moderate.
47. Paternal Government. In
many of the changes which have been described in this
chapter, the share which government took was one of
the most important influences. In some cases,
as in the laws against enclosures, against the migration
of industry from the towns to the rural districts,
and against usury, the policy of King and Parliament
was not successful in resisting the strong economic
forces which were at work. In others, however,
as in the oversight of industry, in the confiscation
of the property of the gilds devoted to religious uses,
in the settlement of the relations between employers
and employees, in the control of foreign commerce,
the policy of the government really decided what direction
changes should take.
As has been seen in this chapter,
after the accession of Henry VII there was a constant
extension of the sphere of government till it came
to pass laws upon and provide for and regulate almost
all the economic interests of the nation. This
was a result, in the first place, of the breaking
down of those social institutions which had been most
permanent and stable in earlier periods. The manor
system in the country, landlord farming, the manor
courts, labor dues, serfdom, were passing rapidly
away; the old type of gilds, city regulations, trading
at fairs, were no longer so general; it was no longer
foreigners who brought foreign goods to England to
be sold, or bought English goods for exportation.
When these old Customs were changing or passing away,
the national government naturally took charge to prevent
the threatened confusion of the process of disintegration.
Secondly, the government itself, from the latter part
of the fifteenth century onward, became abler and
more vigorous, as has been pointed out in the first
paragraph of this chapter. The Privy Council of
the king exercised larger functions, and extended
its jurisdiction into new fields. Under these
circumstances, when the functions of the central government
were being so widely extended, it was altogether natural
that they should come to include the control of all
forms of industrial life, including agriculture, manufacturing,
commerce, internal trade, labor, and other social
and economic relations. Thirdly, the control
of economic and social matters by the government was
in accordance with contemporary opinions and feelings.
An enlightened absolutism seems to have commended
itself to the most thoughtful men of that time.
A paternalism which regulated a very wide circle of
interests was unhesitatingly accepted and approved.
As a result of the decay of mediaeval conditions,
the strengthening of national government, and the
prevailing view of the proper functions of government,
almost all economic conditions were regulated by the
government to a degree quite unknown before. In
the early part of the period this regulation was more
minute, more intrusive, more evidently directed to
the immediate advantage of government; but by the close
of Elizabeth’s reign a systematic regulation
was established, which, while not controlling every
detail of industrial life, yet laid down the general
lines along which most of industrial life must run.
Some parts of this regulation have already been analyzed.
Perhaps the best instance and one of the most important
parts of it is the Statute of Apprentices of 1563,
already described in paragraph 40. In the same
year, 1563, a statute was passed full of minute regulations
for the fishing and fish-dealing trades. Foreign
commerce was carried on by regulated companies; that
is, companies having charters from the government,
giving them a monopoly of the trade with certain countries,
and laying down at least a part of the rules under
which that trade should be carried on. The importation
of most kinds of finished goods and the exportation
of raw materials were prohibited. New industries
were encouraged by patents or other government concessions.
Many laws were passed, of which that of 1571, to encourage
the industry of making caps, is a type. This law
laid down the requirement that every person of six
years old and upward should wear on every Sunday and
holy day a woollen cap made in England.
The conformity to standard of manufactures
was enforced either by the officers of companies which
were established under the authority of the government
or by government officials or patentees, and many of
the methods and standards of manufacture were themselves
defined by statutes or proclamation. In agriculture,
while the policy was less consistent, government regulation
was widely applied. There were laws, as has been
noted, forbidding the possession of more than two thousand
sheep by any one landholder and of more than two farms
by any one tenant; laws requiring the keeping of one
cow and one calf for every sixty sheep, and the raising
a quarter of an acre of flax or hemp for every sixty
acres devoted to other crops. The most characteristic
laws for the regulation of agriculture, however, were
those controlling the export of grain. In order
to prevent an excessive price, grain-raisers were
not allowed to export wheat or other grain when it
was scarce in England. When it was cheap and
plenty, they were permitted to do so, the conditions
under which it was to be allowed or forbidden being
decided, according to a law of 1571, by the justices
of the peace of each locality, with the restriction
that none should be exported when the prevailing price
was more than 1_s._ 3_d._ a bushel, a limit which
was raised to 2_s._ 6_d._ in 1592.
Thus, instead of industrial life being
controlled and regulated by town governments, merchant
and craft gilds, lords of fairs, village communities,
lords of manors and their stewards, or other local
bodies, it was now regulated in its main features by
the all-powerful national government.