While Washington was bearing with
military fortitude the rigors and annoyances of the
imitation court in which he was confined, Congress
reached decisions that had a vast effect in determining
the actual character of the government. The first
business in order of course was the raising of revenue,
for the treasury was empty, and payments of interest
due on the French and Spanish loans were years behind.
Madison attacked this problem before Washington arrived
in New York to take the oath of office. On April
8 he introduced in the House a resolution which aimed
only at giving immediate effect to a scheme of duties
and imposts that had been approved generally by the
States in 1783. On the very next day debate upon
this resolution began in the committee of the whole,
for there was then no system of standing committees
to intervene between the House and its business.
The debate soon broadened out far beyond the lines
of the original scheme, and in it the student finds
lucidly presented the issues of public policy that
have accompanied tariff debates ever since.
Madison laid down the general principle
that “commerce ought to be free, and labor and
industry left at large to find its proper object,”
but suggested that it would be unwise to apply this
principle without regard to particular circumstances.
“Although interest will, in general, operate
effectually to produce political good, yet there are
causes in which certain factitious circumstances may
divert it from its natural channel, or throw or retain
it in an artificial one.” In language which
now reads like prophecy he referred to cases “where
cities, companies, or opulent individuals engross
the business from others, by having had an uninterrupted
possession of it, or by the extent of their capitals
being able to destroy a competition.” The
same situation could occur between nations, and had
to be considered. There was some truth, he also
thought, in the opinion “that each nation should
have within itself the means of defense, independent
of foreign supplies,” but he considered that
this argument had been urged beyond reason, as “there
is good reason to believe that, when it becomes necessary,
we may obtain supplies abroad as readily as any other
nation whatsoever.” He instanced as a cogent
reason in favor of protective duties that, as the
States had formerly the power of making regulations
of trade to cherish their domestic interests, it must
be presumed that, when they put the exercise of this
power into other hands by adopting the Constitution,
“they must have done this with the expectation
that those interests would not be neglected”
by Congress.
Actuated by such views, and doubtless
also influenced by the great need for revenue, Madison
was on the whole favorable to amendments extending
the list of dutiable articles. Though there were
conflicts between members from manufacturing districts
and those from agricultural constituencies, and though
the salt protectionists of New York had some difficulty
in carrying their point, the contention did not follow
sectional lines. Coal was added to the list on
the motion of a member from Virginia. The duties
levied were, however, very moderate, ranging from five
to twelve and one-half per cent, with an exception
in the case of one article that might be considered
a luxury.
The bill as it passed the House discriminated
in favor of nations with which the United States had
commercial treaties. That is to say, it favored
France and Holland as against Great Britain, which
had the bulk of America’s foreign trade.
Though Madison insisted on this provision and was
supported by a large majority of the House, the Senate
would not agree to it. During the early sessions
of Congress the Senate met behind closed doors, a
practice which it did not abandon until five years
later. From the accounts of the discussion preserved
in Maclay’s diary it appears that there was
much wrangling. Maclay relates that on one occasion
when Pennsylvania’s demands were sharply attacked,
his colleague, Robert Morris, was so incensed that
Maclay “could see his nostrils widen and his
nose flatten like the head of a viper.”
Pierce Butler of South Carolina “flamed away
and threatened a dissolution of the Union, with regard
to his State, as sure as God was in the firmament.”
Thus began a line of argument that was frequently
pursued thereafter until it was ended by wager of
battle. On several occasions the division was
so close that Vice-President Adams gave the casting
vote. Although there was much railing in the Senate
against imposts as a burden to the agricultural sections,
yet some who opposed duties in the abstract thought
of particulars that ought not to be neglected if the
principle of protection were admitted. Duties
on hemp and cotton therefore found their way into
the bill through amendments voted by the Senate.
Adjustment of the differences between the two houses
was hindered by the resentment of the House at the
removal of the treaty discrimination feature, but
the Senate with characteristic address evaded the
issue by promising to deal with it as a separate measure
and ended by thwarting the House on that point.
On the whole, in view of the sharp
differences of opinion, the action taken on the tariff
was remarkably expeditious. The bill, which passed
the House on May 16, was passed by the Senate on June
2, and although delay now ensued because of the conflict
over the discrimination issue, the bill became law
by the President’s approval on July 4. This
prompt conclusion in spite of closely-balanced factions
becomes more intelligible when it is observed that
the rules of the Senate then provided that, “in
case of a debate becoming tedious, four Senators may
call for the question.” Brief as was the
period of consideration as compared with the practice
since that day, Maclay noted indignantly that the merchants
had “already added the amount of the duties
to the price of their goods” so that a burden
fell upon the consumers without advantage to the Treasury.
Such consequence is evidence of defect in procedure
which the experience of other nations has led them
to correct, but which has continued to increase in
the United States until it has attained monstrous proportions.
Under the English budget system new imposts now take
effect as soon as they are proposed by the government,
the contingency of alteration in the course of enactment
being provided for by return of payments made in error.
The general tendency of civilized government is now
strongly in favor of attaching the process of deliberation
upon financial measures to the period of their administrative
incubation, and of shortening the period of formal
legislative consideration.
One of the tasks of Congress in its
first session was to draught amendments to the Constitution.
The reasons for such action were stated by Madison
to be a desire to propitiate those who desired a bill
of rights, and an effort to secure acceptance of the
Constitution in Rhode Island and North Carolina.
Promises had been made, in the course of the struggle
for adoption, that this matter would be taken up,
and there was a general willingness to proceed with
it. Under the leadership of Madison, the House
adopted seventeen amendments, which were reduced by
the Senate to twelve. Of these, ten were eventually
ratified and formed what is commonly known as the
Bill of Rights.
Apart from this matter, the session,
which lasted until September 29, was almost wholly
occupied with measures to organize the new government.
To understand the significance of the action taken,
it should be remembered that the passions excited
by the struggle over the new Constitution were still
turbulent. Fisher Ames of Massachusetts, a member
without previous national experience, who watched
the proceedings with keen observation, early noticed
the presence of a group of objectors whose motives
he regarded as partly factious and partly temperamental.
Writing to a friend about the character of the House,
he remarked: “Three sorts of people are
often troublesome: the anti-federals, who alone
are weak and some of them well disposed; the dupes
of local prejudices, who fear eastern influence, monopolies,
and navigation acts; and lastly the violent republicans,
as they think fit to style themselves, who are new
lights in politics, who are more solicitous to establish,
or rather to expatiate upon, some sounding principle
of republicanism, than to protect property, cement
the union, and perpetuate liberty.” The
spirit of opposition had from the first an experienced
leader in Elbridge Gerry of Massachusetts. He
had seen many years of service in the Continental
Congress which he first entered in 1776. He was
a delegate to the Philadelphia convention, in whose
sessions he showed a contentious temper, and in the
end refused to subscribe to the new Constitution.
In the convention debates he had strongly declared
himself “against letting the heads of the departments,
particularly of finance, have anything to do with business
connected with legislation.” Defeated in
the convention, Gerry was now bent upon making his
ideas prevail in the organization of the government.
On May 19, the matter of the executive
departments was brought up in committee of the whole
by Boudinot of New Jersey. At this time it was
the practice of Congress to take up matters first
in committee of the whole, and, after general conclusions
had been reached, to appoint a committee to prepare
and bring in a bill. A warm discussion ensued
on the question whether the heads of the departments
should be removable by the President. Gerry,
who did not take a prominent part in the debate, spoke
with a mildness that was in marked contrast with the
excitement shown by some of the speakers. He
was in favor of supporting the President to the utmost
and of making him as responsible as possible, but since
Congress had obviously no right to confer a power
not authorized by the Constitution, and since the
Constitution had conditioned appointments on the consent
of the Senate, it followed that removals must be subject
to the same condition. He spoke briefly and only
once, although the debate became long and impassioned.
But he was merely reserving his fire, as subsequent
developments soon showed. Without a call for the
ayes and nays, the question was decided in favor of
declaring the power of removal to be in the President.
The committee then proceeded to the consideration of
the Treasury Department. Gerry at once made a
plea for delay. “He thought they were hurrying
on business too rapidly. Gentlemen had already
committed themselves on one very important point.”
He “knew nothing of the system which gentlemen
proposed to adopt in arranging the Treasury Department,”
but the fact was worth considering that “the
late Congress had, on long experience, thought proper
to organize the Treasury Department, in a mode different
from that now proposed.” He “would
be glad to know what the reasons were that would induce
the committee to adopt a different system from that
which had been found most beneficial to the United
States.”
What Gerry had in view was the retention
of the then existing system of Treasury management
by a Board of Commissioners. In 1781 the Continental
Congress had been forced to let the Treasury pass out
of its own hands into those of a Superintendent of
Finance, through sheer inability to get any funds
unless the change was made. Robert Morris, who
held the position, had resigned in January, 1783,
because of the behavior of Congress, but the attitude
of the army had become so menacing that he was implored
to remain in office and attend to the arrears of military
pay. He had managed to effect a settlement, and
at length retired from office on November 1, 1784.
Congress then put the Treasury in the hands of three
commissioners appointed and supervised by it.
Gerry was now striving to continue this arrangement
with as little change as possible.
When debate was resumed the next day,
Gerry made a long, smooth speech on the many superior
advantages of the Board system. The extent and
variety of the functions of the office would be a
trial to any one man’s integrity. “Admit
these innumerable opportunities for defrauding the
revenue, without check or control, and it is next to
impossible he should remain unsullied in reputation,
or innoxious with respect to misapplying his trust.”
The situation would be “Very disagreeable to
the person appointed, provided he is an honest, upright
man; it will be disagreeable also to the people of
the Union, who will always have reason to suspect”
misconduct. “We have had a Board of Treasury
and we have had a Financier. Have not express
charges, as well as vague rumors, been brought against
him at the bar of the public? They may be unfounded,
it is true; but it shows that a man cannot serve in
such a station without exciting popular clamor.
It is very well known, I dare say, to many gentlemen
in this House, that the noise and commotion were such
as obliged Congress once more to alter their Treasury
Department, and place it under the management of a
Board of Commissioners.” He descanted upon
the perils to liberty involved in the course they
were pursuing. Surround the President with Ministers
of State and “the President will be induced to
place more confidence in them than in the Senate....
An oligarchy will be confirmed upon the ruin of the
democracy; a government most hateful will descend to
our posterity and all our exertions in the glorious
cause of freedom will be frustrated.”
Gerry’s speech as a whole was
tactful and persuasive, but he made a blunder when
he appealed to the recollections of the old members,
men who had been in the Continental Congress, or else
in some position where they could view its springs
of action. Their recollections now came forward
to his discomfiture. “My official duty,”
said Wadsworth of Connecticut, “has led me often
to attend at the Treasury of the United States, and,
from my experience, I venture to pronounce that a
Board of Treasury is the worst of all institutions.
They have doubled our national debt.” He
contrasted the order and clearness of accounts while
the Superintendent of Finance was in charge with the
situation since then. If the committee had before
them the transactions of the Treasury Board, “instead
of system and responsibility they would find nothing
but confusion and disorder, without a possibility
of checking their accounts.” Boudinot of
New Jersey said he “would state a circumstance
which might give the committee some small idea of
what the savings under the Superintendent were.
The expenditure of hay at a certain post was one hundred
and forty tons; such was the estimate laid before
him; yet twelve tons carried the post through the year,
and the supply was abundant, and the post was as fully
and usefully occupied as it had ever been before.”
Of course there was an outcry against the Superintendent
of Finance; “he rather wondered that the clamor
was not more loud and tremendous.” He remembered
that “one hundred and forty-six supernumerary
officers were brushed off in one day, who had long
been sucking the vital blood and spirit of the nation.
Was it to be wondered at, if this swarm should raise
a buzz about him?” Gerry fought on almost singlehanded,
but he could not refute the evidence that he had invited.
He lost his temper and resorted to sarcasm. If
a single head of the Treasury was so desirable, why
not “have a single legislator; one man to make
all the laws, the revenue laws particularly, because
among many there is less responsibility, system, and
energy; consequently a numerous representation in
this House is an odious institution.”
The case for the Treasury Board was
so hopeless that nothing more was heard of it; but
the battle over the removal question was renewed with
added violence, when the bill for establishing the
Department of Foreign Affairs came up for consideration.
White of Virginia now led the attack. He had
been a member of the Continental Congress from 1786
to 1788, and a member of the ratifying convention
of his State. Although he voted for a provisional
acceptance of the Constitution, he had supported an
amendment requiring Congress to collect direct taxes
or excises through State agency, which would have
been in effect a return to the plan of requisitions the
bane of the Confederation. In an elaborate speech
he attacked the clause giving the President power
to remove from office, as an attempt to impart an
authority not conferred by the Constitution, and inconsistent
with the requirement that appointments should be made
with the advice and consent of the Senate. The
debate soon became heated. “Let us look
around at this moment,” said Jackson of Georgia,
“and see the progress we are making toward venality
and corruption. We already hear the sounding
title of Highness and Most Honorable
trumpeted in our ears, which, ten years since, would
have exalted a man to a station as high as Haman’s
gibbet.” Page of Virginia was ablaze with
indignation. “Good God!” he exclaimed.
“What, authorize in a free republic, by law,
too, by your first act, the exertion of a dangerous
royal prerogative in your Chief Magistrate!”
Gerry, in remarks whose oblique criticism upon arrangements
at the President’s house was perfectly well understood,
dwelt upon the possibility that the President might
be guided by some other criterion than discharge of
duty as the law directs. “Perhaps the officer
is not good natured enough; he makes an ungraceful
bow, or does it left leg foremost; this is unbecoming
in a great officer at the President’s levee.
Now, because he is so unfortunate as not to be so good
a dancer as he is a worthy officer, he must be removed.”
These rhetorical flourishes, which are significant
of the undercurrent of sentiment, hardly do justice
to the general quality of the debate which was marked
by legal acuteness on both sides. Madison pressed
home the sensible argument that the President could
not be held to responsibility unless he could control
his subordinates. “And if it should happen
that the officers connect themselves with the Senate,
they may mutually support each other, and for want
of efficacy reduce the power of the President to a
mere vapor; in which case, his responsibility would
be annihilated and the expectation of it unjust.”
The debate lasted for several days,
but Madison won by a vote of 34 to 20 in committee,
in favor of retaining the clause. On second thought,
however, and probably after consultation with the little
group of constructive statesmen who stood behind the
scenes, he decided that it might be dangerous to allow
the President’s power of removal to rest upon
a legislative grant that might be revoked. When
the report from the committee of the whole was taken
up in the House, a few days later, Benson of New York
proposed that the disputed clause should be omitted
and the language of the bill should be worded so as
to imply that the power of removal was in the President.
Madison accepted the suggestion, and the matter was
thus settled. The point was covered by providing
that the chief clerk of the Department should take
charge “whenever the principal officer shall
be removed from office by the President.”
The clause got through the Senate by the casting vote
of the Vice-President, and a similar provision was
inserted, without further contest, in all the acts
creating the executive departments. It is rather
striking evidence of the Utopian expectations which
could then be indulged that Daniel Carroll of Maryland
was persistent in urging that the existence of the
office should be limited to a few years, “under
a hope that a time would come when the United States
would be disengaged from the necessity of supporting
a Secretary of Foreign Affairs.” Although
Gerry and others expressed sympathy with the motion
it was voted down without a division.
When the bill establishing the Treasury
Department was taken up, Page of Virginia made a violent
attack upon the clause authorizing the Secretary to
“digest and report plans.” He denounced
it as “an attempt to create an undue influence”
in the House. “Nor would the mischief stop
here; it would establish a precedent which might be
extended until we admitted all the Ministers of the
government on the floor, to explain and support the
plans they have digested and reported; thus laying
the foundation for an aristocracy or a detestable
monarchy.” As a matter of fact, a precedent
in favor of access to Congress already existed.
The old Superintendent of Finance and the Board which
succeeded him had the power now proposed for the Secretary
of the Treasury. Livermore of New Hampshire, who
had been a member of the Continental Congress, admitted
this fact, but held that such power was not dangerous
at that time since Congress then possessed both legislative
and executive authority. They could abolish his
plans and his office together, if they thought proper;
“but we are restrained by a Senate and by the
negative of the President,” Gerry declared his
assent to the views expressed by Page. “If
the doctrine of having prime and great ministers of
state was once well established, he did not doubt but
that we should soon see them distinguished by a green
or red ribbon, or other insignia of court favor and
patronage.”
The strongest argument in favor of
retaining the clause referred to was made by Fisher
Ames, who had begun to display the powers of clear
statement and of convincing argument that soon established
his supremacy in debate. He brought the debate
at once to its proper bearings by pointing out that
there were really only two matters to be considered:
whether the proposed arrangement was useful, and whether
it could be safely guarded from abuse. “The
Secretary is presumed to acquire the best knowledge
of the subject of finance of any member of the community.
Now, if this House is to act on the best knowledge
of circumstances, it seems to follow logically that
the House must obtain the evidence from that officer:
the best way of doing this will be publicly from the
officer himself, by making it his duty to furnish
us with it.” In one of those eloquent passages
which brighten the records of debate whenever Ames
spoke at any length, he pictured the difficulties
that had to be surmounted. “If we consider
the present situation of our finances, owing to a variety
of causes, we shall no doubt perceive a great, although
unavoidable confusion throughout the whole scene;
it presents to the imagination a deep, dark, and dreary
chaos; impossible to be reduced to order without the
mind of the architect is clear and capacious, and
his power commensurate to the occasion.”
He asked, “What improper influence could a plan
reported openly and officially have on the mind of
any member, more than if the scheme and information
were given privately at the Secretary’s office?”
Merely to call for information would not be advantageous
to the House. “It will be no mark of inattention
or neglect, if he take time to consider the questions
you propound; but if you make it his duty to furnish
you plans ... and he neglect to perform it, his conduct
or capacity is virtually impeached. This will
be furnishing an additional check.”
Sedgwick of Massachusetts made a strong
speech to the same effect. “Make your officer
responsible,” he said with prophetic vision,
“and the presumption is, that plans and information
are properly digested; but if he can secrete himself
behind the curtain, he might create a noxious influence,
and not be answerable for the information he gives.”
The weight of the argument was heavily
on the side of the supporters of the clause, and it
looked as though the group of objectors would again
be beaten. But now a curious thing happened.
Fitzsimmons remarked that, if he understood the objection
made to the clause, “it was a jealousy arising
from the power given the Secretary to report plans
of revenue to the House.” He suggested
that “harmony might be restored by changing the
word ‘report’ into ’prepare’.”
Fitzsimmons was esteemed by the House because of his
zealous support of the War of Independence and also
because he stood high as a successful Philadelphia
merchant, but he did not, however, rank as a leader.
Early in the session Ames described him as a man who
“is supposed to understand trade, and he assumes
some weight in such matters. He is plausible,
though not over civil; is artful, has a glaring eye,
a down look, speaks low, and with apparent candor
and coolness.” He was hardly the man to
guide the House on a matter pertaining to the organization
of public authority.
While the removal issue was before
the House, Madison had been prominent in debate, and
had spoken with great power and earnestness; but up
to this time he had said nothing on the issue now
pending. He now remarked that he did not believe
that the danger apprehended by some really existed,
but twice in his speech he admitted that “there
is a small possibility, though it is but small, that
an officer may derive a weight from this circumstance,
and have some degree of influence upon the deliberations
of the legislature.” In its practical effect
the speech favored the compromise which Fitzsimmons
had just proposed; in fact, the only opposition to
the change of phrasing now came from a few extremists
who still clamored for the omission of the entire
clause. The decisive effect of Madison’s
intervention was a natural consequence of the leadership
he had held in the movement for the new Constitution
and of his standing as the representative of the new
Administration, of his possessing Washington’s
confidence and acting as his adviser. Washington,
then being without a cabinet, had turned to Madison
for help in discharging the duties of his office,
and at Washington’s written request Madison had
drafted for him his replies to the addresses of the
House and the Senate at the opening of the session.
It was a matter of course in such circumstances that
the House accepted Fitzsimmons’ amendment, “by
a great majority,” according to the record, and
thus the Secretary of the Treasury was shut out of
the House and was condemned to work in the lobby.
The consequences of this decision
have been so vast that it is worth while making an
inquiry into motive, although the materials upon which
judgment must rest are scant. No one can read
the record of this discussion without noting that
Madison’s approval of the original clause was
lukewarm as compared with the ardor he had shown when
the question was whether Washington should be allowed
to remove his subordinates. This contrast suggests
that Madison’s behavior was affected by fear
of Hamilton’s influence. Would it be prudent
for him to give Hamilton the advantage of being able
to appear in person before the House, and probably
to supplant Madison himself as the spokesman of the
Administration? Divergence between the two men
had already begun in details. At the time the
vote on the powers of the Secretary of the Treasury
was taken, the tariff bill and the tonnage bill were
still pending, and Hamilton’s influence operated
against Madison’s views on some points.
Moreover, the question of the permanent residence
of the federal government was coming forward and was
apparently overshadowing everything else in the minds
of members. Ames several times in his correspondence
at this period remarks upon Madison’s timidity,
which was due to his concern about Virginia State politics.
Any arrangement that might enable Hamilton to cross
swords with an opponent on the floor of the House
could not be attractive to Madison, who was a lucid
reasoner but not an impressive speaker. Hamilton
was both of these, and he possessed an intellectual
brilliancy which Madison lacked. Ames, who respected
Madison’s abilities and who regarded him as the
leading member of the House, wrote that “he
speaks low, his person is little and ordinary; he
speaks decently as to manner, and no more; his language
is very pure, perspicuous, and to the point.”
Why Fitzsimmons should be opposed to the appearance
of the Secretary in person in the House, as had been
Robert Morris’s practice when he was Superintendent
of Finance, is plain enough. Maclay’s diary
has many references to Fitzsimmons’s negotiations
with members on tariff rates. It was not to the
advantage of private diplomacy to allow the Secretary
to shape and define issues on the floor of the House.
But Fitzsimmons could not have had his way about the
matter without Madison’s help.
Gibbon remarks that the greatest of
theological controversies which racked the Roman Empire
and affected the peace of millions turned on the question
whether a certain word should be spelled with one diphthong
or another. A like disproportion between the
vastness of results and the minuteness of verbal distinction
is exhibited in this decision by the House. The
change of “report” into “prepare”
threw up a ridge in the field of constitutional development
that has affected the trend of American politics ever
since. This is the explanation of a problem of
comparative politics that has often excited much wondering
notice: why it is that alone among modern representative
assemblies the American House of Representatives tends
to decline in prestige and authority. The original
expectation was that the House of Representatives
would take a dominant position like that of the House
of Commons, but its degradation began so soon that
Fisher Ames noted it as early as 1797. Writing
to Hamilton he observed:
“The heads of departments are
chief clerks. Instead of being the ministry,
the organs of the executive power, and imparting a
kind of momentum to the operation of the laws, they
are precluded even from communicating with the House
by reports.... Committees already are the Ministers
and while the House indulges a jealousy of encroachment
in its functions, which are properly deliberative,
it does not perceive that these are impaired and nullified
by the monopoly as well as the perversion of information
by these committees.”
Justice Story, who entered Congress
in 1808 as a Jeffersonian Republican, noted the process
of degradation, and in his Commentaries he pointed
out the cause: “The Executive is compelled
to resort to secret and unseen influences, to private
interviews and private arrangements to accomplish
its own appropriate purposes, instead of proposing
and sustaining its own duties and measures by a bold
and manly appeal to the nation in the face of its
representatives.”
The last of the organic acts of the
session was the one establishing the judiciary.
The student will be disappointed if he examines the
record to note whether there was any vision of the
ascendancy which the judiciary was to obtain in the
development of the American constitutional system.
The debates were almost wholly about the possibilities
of conflict between the state and the federal courts.
Although Maclay’s diary gives a one-sided and
distorted account of the proceedings in the Senate,
the course of the debate is clear. Ellsworth
of Connecticut had principal charge of the bill.
At the outset Lee and Grayson of Virginia made an
ineffectual effort to confine the original jurisdiction
of the federal courts to cases of admiralty and maritime
jurisdiction, and argued that jurisdiction over other
cases involving federal law might be conferred upon
state courts. This was a point on which there
had been some difference of opinion between Hamilton
and Madison. The former held that it was within
the competency of Congress, when instituting tribunals
inferior to the Supreme Court, to adopt the state courts
for that purpose. Madison held that nothing less
than a system of federal courts quite distinct from
the state courts would satisfy the requirements of
the Constitution. When the bill was taken up
in the House, there was a long debate over this matter.
The costly duplication of judicial establishments
that has ever since existed in the United States is
certainly not necessary to a federal system, but is
an American peculiarity. The advocates of a unified
system were hampered by the fact that this view was
pressed by some in a spirit of hostility to the Constitution.
The decisive argument was the untrustworthiness of
the state courts. Madison urged this fact with
great force and pointed out that in some of the States
the courts “are so dependent on the state legislatures,
that to make the federal laws dependent on them, would
throw us back into all the embarrassments which characterized
our former situation.” Such was the low
repute of the state legislatures that the only way
in which this argument could be met was to argue that
“Congress shall have power, in its fullest extent,
to correct, reverse, or affirm, any decree of a state
court.” This high assertion of federal
authority was made by Jackson of Georgia in the course
of a long legal argument. The debate did not follow
sectional lines, and in general it was not unfairly
described by Maclay as a lawyer’s wrangle.
The bill was put into shape by the Senate, and reached
the House toward the close of the session when the
struggle over the site of the national capital was
overshadowing everything else. It was so generally
believed that nothing important could be gained by
attempts at amendment that, after an airing of opinions,
the House accepted the measure just as it had come
from the Senate.