The subject of national finance had
long interested Hamilton. His ideas had been
matured by a diligent and minute study of English precedents,
and now that his opportunity had come he was ready
to grasp it. Soon after he took office, the House
resolved that “an adequate provision for the
support of the public credit” should be made,
and it directed the Secretary of the Treasury “to
prepare a plan for that purpose and to report the
same to the House at its next meeting.”
This was, in effect, a postponement until the second
session of the First Congress, which began in January,
1790. In his opening address to Congress, Washington
pointedly referred to the public credit resolution
which he had noted “with peculiar pleasure.”
On the next day a letter from Hamilton was read in
the House stating that he had prepared his plan and
was ready to report the same to the House when they
should be pleased to receive it.
This announcement brought up anew
the question in what manner the Secretary should make
his report. Gerry was on his feet at once with
a motion that it should be made in writing. Boudinot
“hoped that the Secretary of the Treasury might
be permitted to make his report in person in order
to answer such inquiries as the members might be disposed
to make, for it was a justifiable surmise that gentlemen
would not be able clearly to comprehend so intricate
a subject without oral illustration.” The
allusion to the intricacy of the subject had the effect
of turning against the plan of oral communication
some who had favored giving the Secretary the same
direct access to Congress that the Superintendent of
Finance had formerly enjoyed. Ames, for instance,
now desired that the Secretary’s communications
should be in writing since “in this shape they
would obtain a degree of permanency favorable to the
responsibility of the officer, while, at the same
time, they would be less liable to be misunderstood.”
Benson suggested that since the resolution of Congress
had directed the Secretary to make a report, it was
left to his discretion to “make it in the manner
for which he is prepared.” Gerry adroitly
countered by saying that the resolution provided for
a report. That done, it would be time enough
“to give him the right to lay before them his
explanations, if he thinks explanations necessary.”
The debate was brief and one-sided; the motion for
receiving the report in writing was adopted without
a division. Five days later the written report
was laid before the House, but the Secretary was never
accorded an opportunity to offer any personal explanations.
This masterly report, which is justly
regarded as the corner-stone of American public credit,
excites the admiration of the reader by the clearness
of its analysis, the cogency of its argument, and the
broad range of its vision. The principles of
action that it embodied, however, were few and simple,
chief among them being exact and punctual fulfillment
of contract. “States, like individuals,
who observe their engagements, are respected and trusted;
while the reverse is the fate of those who pursue
an opposite conduct.” To discharge the principal
of the public debt was of course impracticable; nor
was it desirable, as the creditors would be well pleased
to leave it at interest. Incidentally the funding
of the debt would provide securities that would serve
trade as a species of currency, and would set in motion
a long train of benefits that would extend throughout
the community. In the funding operation the debts
contracted by the States should be included.
As to this Hamilton remarked: “The general
principle of it seems to be equitable, for it seems
difficult to conceive a good reason why the expenses
for the particular defense of a part in a common war
should not be a common charge, as well as those incurred
professedly for the general defense. The defense
of each part is that of the whole; and unless the
expenditures are brought into a common mass, the tendency
must be to add to the calamities suffered by being
the most exposed to the ravages of war and increase
of burthens.”
Hamilton computed the amount of the
foreign debt, principal and arrears, at $11,710,378.62;
the domestic debt, including that of the States, at
$42,414,085.94, a total of over fifty-four
millions with an annual interest charge at existing
rates amounting to $4,587,444.81, a staggering
total for a nation whose revenue was then insufficient
to meet its current expenses. Nevertheless Hamilton
refused to admit that “such a provision would
exceed the abilities of the country,” but he
was “clearly of the opinion that to make it
would require the extension of taxation to a degree
and to objects which the true interest of the public
creditor forbids.” He therefore favored
a composition, in arranging which there would be strict
adherence to the principle “that no change in
the rights of creditors ought to be attempted without
their voluntary consent; and that this consent ought
to be voluntary in fact as well as in name.”
It followed that “every proposal of a change
ought to be in the shape of an appeal to their interests;
but not to their necessities.” Hamilton
then went into details of a funding loan, in which
various options were offered to the creditors, including
land grants in part payment, and conversion in whole
or in part into annuities, several sorts of which were
offered. He submitted estimates of how the various
plans would work out in practice, and he concluded
that the annual revenue which would be required to
enable the government to meet its obligations under
the scheme and also to maintain its current service
would amount to $2,239,163.09, a sum that could be
readily provided.
There could not have been a more striking
contrast than there was between the humiliating conditions
which actually existed and the grand results which
Hamilton designed and confidently expected. The
ardent and hopeful tone of his plan, conceived in
apparently desperate circumstances, is very marked.
He declared: “It cannot but merit particular
attention that among ourselves the most enlightened
friends of good government are those whose expectations
are the highest. To justify and preserve their
confidence; to promote the increasing respectability
of the American name; to answer the calls of justice;
to restore landed property to its due value; to furnish
new resources both to agriculture and commerce; to
cement more closely the union of the States; to add
to their security against foreign attack; to establish
public order on the basis of a liberal and upright
policy these are the great and invaluable
ends to be secured by a proper and adequate provision
at the present period for the support of public credit.”
All these great objects were indeed
attained, but Hamilton’s anticipation of them
was at the time regarded as either a pretext made to
cajole Congress or else merely an ebullition from
his own sanguine nature not to be taken too seriously
by sensible people. Senator Maclay of Pennsylvania
regarded Hamilton’s plans as wildly extravagant
in their conception and iniquitous in their practical
effect. In his opinion, Hamilton had “a
very boyish, giddy manner, and Scotch-Irish people
could well call him a ‘skite.’”
Jackson of Georgia exposed to the House the folly of
Hamilton’s proposals by pointing out that a
funded debt meant national decay. He mentioned
England as “a melancholy instance of the ruin
attending such engagements.” To such a
pitch had the “spirit of funding and borrowing
been carried in that country” that its national
debt was now “a burthen which the most sanguine
mind can never contemplate they will ever be relieved
from.” France also was “considerably
enfeebled and languishes under a heavy load of debt.”
He argued that by funding the debt in America “the
same effect must be produced that has taken place in
other nations; it must either bring on national bankruptcy,
or annihilate her existence as an independent empire.”
Such dismal prognostications on the
very eve of the Napoleonic era, with its tremendous
revelations of national power, were quite common at
that time. The long rambling debate that took
place in the House when Hamilton’s report was
taken up for consideration abounds with similar instances
of shortsightedness. Many members did not scruple
to advise repudiation, in whole or in part. Livermore
of New Hampshire admitted that the foreign debt should
be provided for, since it was “lent to the United
States in real coin, by disinterested persons, not
concerned or benefited by the revolution,” but
that the domestic debt was “for depreciated paper,
or services done at exorbitant rates, or for goods
or provisions supplied at more than their real worth,
by those who received all the benefits arising from
our change of condition.” True, Congress
had pledged its faith to the redemption of issues
at their face value, “but this was done on a
principle of policy, in order to prevent the rapid
depreciation which was taking place.” He
argued that “money lent in this depreciated and
depreciating state can hardly be said to be lent from
a spirit of patriotism; it was a mere speculation
in public securities.”
The distinction between the foreign
debt and the domestic was seized by many members as
providing a just basis for discrimination. Page
of Virginia observed that “our citizens were
deeply interested, and, I believe, if they were never
to get a farthing for what is owing to them for their
services, they would be well paid; they have gained
what they aimed at; they have secured their liberties
and their laws; they will be satisfied that this House
has pledged itself to pay foreigners the generous
loans they advanced to us in the day of distress.”
In the course of the debate the power to do was so
often mentioned as implying the right to do that Ames
was moved to remark: “I have heard that
in the East Indies the stock of the labor and the
property of the empire is the property of the Prince;
that it is held at his will and pleasure; but this
is a slavish doctrine, which I hope we are not prepared
to adopt here.” As a matter of fact, there
had already been extensive scaling of the debt, and
the note emissions had been pretty nearly wiped out.
To save the public credit from complete collapse,
the Continental Congress had entered into definite
contracts under the most solemn pledges, and it was
upon this select class of securities that it was now
proposed to start anew the process of repudiation.
But public opinion displayed itself so hostile to
such perfidy that the party of repudiation in Congress
soon dwindled to insignificance and the struggle finally
settled upon two issues, discrimination and assumption.
Weeks of debate ensued, and the deepest
impression made by a careful perusal of the record
is the inability of members to appreciate the importance
of the issues. Much of the tedious and pointless
character of their speeches may be ascribed to the
lack of the personal presence of the Secretary.
There being nothing to focus the debate and exclude
the fictitious and irrelevant, it rambled in any direction
a speaker’s fancy might suggest. Moreover,
its quality was impaired because any consideration
of motive was of the nature of talking about a man
behind his back and this, everyone knows, is very
different from saying things to his face. Assertions
and innuendos which would hardly have been hazarded
had Hamilton been present, or which, had they been
made, would have been forthwith met and refuted, were
indulged in without restraint. Although one of
the reasons given for requiring a written report was
that the House would be the better informed, the debate
does not indicate that the arguments by which Hamilton
had vindicated his proposals had really been apprehended.
The question whether or not any discrimination
could be made between original holders of the public
securities and those who had acquired them by purchase
was considered at length by Hamilton in his report.
The public securities had been at such a heavy discount
that now, if they were to be met at face value, speculators
would reap large profits. Hamilton put the case
of the opposition as strongly as possible. It
might be urged that it was unreasonable “to
pay twenty shillings in the pound to one who had not
given more for it than three or four; and it is added
that it would be hard to aggravate the misfortune
of the first owner, who, probably through necessity,
parted with, his property at so great a loss, by obliging
him to contribute to the profit of the person who
had speculated on his distresses.” Nevertheless,
Hamilton submitted considerations showing that discrimination
would be “equally unjust and impolitic, as highly
injurious even to the original holders of public securities,
as ruinous to public credit.” It is unnecessary
to repeat the lucid argument by which Hamilton demonstrated
the soundness of his position, for security of transfer
is now well understood to be an essential element
of public credit; but the special point of interest
is that the debate simply ignored Hamilton’s
argument and rambled along over the superficial aspects
of the case, dwelling upon the sorrows of those who
had parted with their holdings, and exhibiting their
situation as the most important matter to be considered.
Madison was most active in making
that branch of the case the leading issue, and in
a series of elaborate speeches which cannot now be
read without regret, he urged that the present holders
should be allowed only the highest market price previously
recorded, and that the residue should go to the original
holders. Boudinot at once pointed out that there
was nothing on record to show who might be an original
bona fide holder. Great quantities of the certificates
of indebtedness had, as a mere matter of convenience,
been issued to government clerks who afterwards distributed
them among those who furnished supplies to the government
or who performed services entitling them to pay.
He mentioned that he himself appeared on the record
as original holder in cases wherein he had really acted
in behalf of his neighbors to relieve them of the
trouble of personal appearance. Madison’s
proposition would therefore invest him with a legal
title to property which really belonged to others.
But this and other evidence of the real effect of
Madison’s proposal failed to move him, further
than to cause him to declare that “all that he
wished was that the claims of the original holders,
not less than those of the actual holders, should
be fairly examined and justly decided,” Finally
Benson of New York gave him a shrewd home thrust that
plainly embarrassed him. He put the question
whether, if he had purchased a certificate from Madison,
and the Treasury withheld part of the amount for Madison
as the original holder, Madison would keep the money?
“I ask,” said Benson, “whether he
would take advantage of the law against me, and refuse
to give me authority to take it up in his name?”
Madison evaded the query by saying that everything
would depend upon the circumstances of any particular
case, and that circumstances were conceivable in which
the most tender conscience need not refrain from taking
the benefit of what the government had determined.
The debate on Madison’s discrimination
amendment lasted from the eleventh to the twenty-second
day of February Washington’s birthday.
The House did honor to the day when it rejected Madison’s
motion by the crushing vote of 36 to 13. With
that, his pretensions to the leadership of the House
quite disappeared.
The assumption of state debts was
the subject of a debate in committee of the whole
which lasted from the twenty-third of February to the
second of March. New factional lines now revealed
a supposed diversity of interest of the several States.
The false notions of finance then current were illustrated
by an argument that was in continual use, either on
the floor or in the lobby. Members would figure
how much their States would have to pay as their share
of the debt that would be assumed, and on that basis
would reach conclusions as to how their States stood
to win or lose by the transaction. By this reckoning,
of course, the great gainer would appear to be the
State upon whom the chances of war had piled the largest
debt. This calculation made Burke of South Carolina,
usually an opponent of anything coming from Hamilton,
a strong advocate of assumption. He told the
House that “if the present question was lost,
he was almost certain it would end in her bankruptcy,
for she [South Carolina] was no more able to grapple
with her enormous debt than a boy of twelve years of
age is able to grapple with a giant.” Livermore,
representing a State never within the actual field
of military operations, at once replied: “I
conceive that the debt of South Carolina, or Massachusetts,
or of an individual, has nothing to do with our deliberations.
If they have involved themselves in debt, it is their
misfortune, and they must extricate themselves as well
as they can.” On a later occasion Stone
of Maryland, another State that lay outside the track
of war, gave the leading war-debt States an admonition
of the kind that adds insult to injury, saying “however
inconvenient it may be to Massachusetts or South Carolina
to make a bold exertion, and nobly bear the burthens
of their present debt, I believe in the end it would
be found to conduce greatly to their advantage.”
Burke made a crushing rejoinder. “Was Maryland
like South Carolina constantly grappling with the
enemy during the whole war? There is not a road
in the State but has witnessed the ravages of war;
plantations were destroyed, and the skeletons of houses,
to this day, point out to the traveler the route of
the British army; her citizens were exposed to every
violence, their capital taken, and their country almost
overrun by the enemy; men, women, and children murdered
by the Indians and Tories; all the personal property
consumed, and now is it to be wondered at that she
is not able to make exertions equal with other States,
who have been generally in an undisturbed condition?”
The argument pressed by the advocates
of assumption was that the state debts contracted
during the Revolutionary War were for the common defense,
and that, unless these were assumed by the general
government, the adoption of the new Constitution would
do injury by withdrawing revenue resources which the
States had formerly possessed. This position at
the present day seems reasonable enough, but it is
certain that at that time people worked themselves
into a genuine rage over the matter and were able
to persuade themselves into a sincere belief that it
was outrageous the unfortunate States should expect
the others to bear their troubles, and that Hamilton
was a great rogue for proposing such a scheme.
Writing in his private diary, Maclay characterized
the plan as “a monument of political absurdity,”
and he was in the habit of referring to Hamilton’s
supporters as his “gladiators” and as a
“corrupt squadron.”
On the whole the records make painful
reading. The prevailing tone of public life was
one of dull and narrow provincialism, at times thickening
into stupidity, at times sharpening into spite, although
ordinarily made respectable by a serious attitude
to life and by a stolid fortitude in facing whatever
the distracted times might present. It was the
influence of a few great men that made America a nation.
If one is not subject to the spirit of ancestor worship
that has long ruled American history, one is bound
to say that apart from some forceful pamphleteering
of transient purpose the voluminous political
literature of the formative period displays much pedantic
erudition but has little that goes really deep.
The Federalist, the artillery of a hard fought
battle, is a striking exception. So, too, is
the series of reports by Hamilton. But his plans
could not prevail by force of reason against the general
spirit of selfish particularism. Although on
March 2 a motion adverse to assumption in committee
of the whole was defeated by a vote of 28 to 22, it
was then known that a majority could not be procured
for enactment, and on April 12 the assumption bill
was defeated outright in the House, 31 to 29.
Maclay, who went over to the House from the Senate
to witness the event, gloated over the defeat in his
diary:
“Sedgwick, from Boston, pronounced
a funeral oration over it. He was called to order;
some confusion ensued; he took his hat and went out.
When he returned, his visage bore the visible marks
of weeping. Fitzsimmons reddened like scarlet;
his eyes were brimful. Clymer’s color, always
pale, now merged to a deadly white; his lips quivered,
and his nether jaw shook with convulsive motions;
his head, neck, and breast contracted with gesticulations
resembling those of a turkey or goose nearly strangled
in the act of deglutition. Benson bungled like
a shoemaker who has lost his end.... Wadsworth
hid his grief under the rim of a round hat. Boudinot’s
wrinkles rose in ridges and the angles of his mouth
were depressed and assumed a curve resembling a horse’s
shoe.” The defeat did not discourage Hamilton.
He had successfully handled a more difficult situation
in getting New York to ratify the Constitution, and,
resorting now to the same means he had then employed,
he used pressure of interest to move those who could
not be stirred by reason. The intense concern
felt by members in the choice of the site of the national
capital supplied him with the leverage which he brought
to bear on the situation. Most of the members
were more stirred by that question than by any other
before Congress. It was a prominent topic in
Madison’s correspondence from the time the Constitution
was adopted. Maclay’s diary abounds with
references to the subject. Some of his bitterest
sentences are penned about the conduct of those who
preferred some other site to that on the Susquehanna
River which he knew to be the best because he lived
there himself. Bargaining among the members as
to the selection had been going on almost from the
first. As early as April 26, 1789, before Washington
had been installed in his office, Maclay mentions
a meeting “to concert some measures for the
removal of Congress.” Thereafter notices
of pending deals appear frequently in his diary.
After the defeat of the assumption bill, the diary
notes the activity of Hamilton in this matter.
An entry of June 14, 1790, ascribes to Robert Morris
the statement that “Hamilton said he wanted
one vote in the Senate and five in the House of Representatives;
that he was willing and would agree to place the permanent
residence of Congress at Germantown or Falls of the
Delaware (Trenton), if he would procure him those
votes.” Although definite knowledge is unattainable,
one gets the impression, in following the devious
course of these intrigues, that had Pennsylvania interests
been united they could have decided the site of the
national capital; but the delegation was divided over
the relative merits of the Delaware and the Susquehanna
as well as on the question of assumption. Hamilton’s
efforts in this quarter were ineffectual, and the
winning combination was finally arranged elsewhere
and otherwise by the aid of Jefferson.
Thomas Jefferson was at this time
forty-seven years old, and owing both to seniority
and to the distinguished positions he had held, he
ranked as the most illustrious member of the Administration.
His correspondence at this period shows that he was
fully aware of the importance of the crisis, and he
did not overrate it when he wrote to James Monroe,
June 20, 1790, that, unless the measures of the Administration
were successful, “our credit will burst and
vanish, and the States separate to take care everyone
of itself.” In this letter Jefferson outlined
the compromise that was actually adopted by Congress.
The strongest opposition to the assumption bill had
come from Virginia, although Maryland, Georgia, and
New Hampshire also opposed it, and the Middle States
were divided. Jefferson was able to get enough
Southern votes to carry assumption in return for enough
votes from Hamilton’s adherents to carry the
Potomac site. An agreement was reached at a dinner
given by Jefferson to which he invited Hamilton and
Madison. According to this arrangement, the capital
was to remain in Philadelphia for ten years and after
that to be on the Potomac River in a district ten
miles square to be selected by the President.
The residence act was approved July 16, 1790; the
funding and assumption measures, now combined in one
bill, became law on August 4.
After Jefferson turned against the
Administration, his participation in the passage of
the assumption bill was such an awkward circumstance
that he discredited his own intelligence by professing
that he “was most ignorantly and innocently
made to hold the candle” to Hamilton’s
“game.” In reality the public service
Jefferson then performed was the most useful in all
his long and fruitful career. But for this action,
the Declaration of Independence, to the drafting of
which he owes his greatest fame, might now be figuring
among the historical documents of lost causes, like
similar elaborate statements of principle made during
the Commonwealth period in England. Had the national
forces failed at the critical period of financial
organization, and the States, bankrupt by the revolutionary
struggle, been left in the lurch, the republic would
have followed the usual course of disintegration displayed
by federations from the time of the Greek amphictyonies
down to that of the Holy Roman Empire.
The charge was made soon after Hamilton’s
victory that it was largely due to the influence of
speculators. The advance in the market value of
securities produced by Hamilton’s measures certainly
gave an opportunity to speculators of which they availed
themselves with the unscrupulous activity characteristic
of the sordid tribe. Jefferson has left an account
of “the base scramble.” “Couriers
and relay horses by land, and swift sailing pilot
boats by sea, were flying in all directions. Active
partners and agents were associated and employed in
every state, town, and country neighborhood, and this
paper was bought up at five shillings, and even as
low as two shillings in the pound, before the holder
knew that Congress had already provided for its assumption
at par. Immense sums were thus filched from the
poor and ignorant, and fortunes accumulated by those
who had themselves been poor enough before.”
This account is highly colored. The struggle was too close, and the issue was
long too doubtful, to admit of speculative preparations extending to every town
and country neighborhood. If speculation took place on such a large scale, it
must have been also taking risks on a large scale, for assumption was not
assured until Jefferson himself put his shoulder to the wheel. The lack of means
for prompt diffusion of intelligence naturally provided large opportunity for
speculation by those in a position to keep well-informed, and undoubtedly large
profits were made; but the circumstances were such that it seems most probable
that profits were less than market opportunities would have allowed had not the
issue been so long in doubt. Nevertheless there was much speculative activity,
and the charge was soon made that it extended into Congress.
The passage of assumption was the
turning point. Other important measures followed,
but none of them met with difficulties which the Administration
could not overcome by ordinary methods of persuasion
and appeal. A national bank was authorized by
an act approved on February 25, 1791. Hamilton’s
famous report on manufactures, a masterly analysis
of the sources of national wealth and of the means
of improving them, was sent to Congress on December
5, 1791. Upon his recommendation Congress established
the mint, the only point which excited controversy
being Hamilton’s proposal that the coins should
be stamped with the head of the President in whose
administration they were issued. This suggestion
was rejected on the ground that it smacked too much
of the practice of monarchies. The queer totemistic
designs of American coinage are a consequence of this
decision.
The formation of national government
by voluntary agreement is a unique event. The
explanation of this peculiar result in the case of
America is the unifying influence of Hamilton’s
measures. They interested in the support of the
government economic forces strong enough to counteract
the separatist tendencies that had always before broken
up states unless they were held together by sheer
might of power in their rulers. The means employed
have been cited as evidence in support of the economic
interpretation of history now in fashion. Government,
it is true, like every other form of life, must meet
the fundamental needs of subsistence and defense,
but this truism supplies no explanation of the particular
mode of doing so that may be adopted. Those needs
account for motion but not for direction. Human
will, discernment, and purpose enter and complicate
the situation in a way that makes theories of determinism
appear absurd. No one has ever contended that
Hamilton was prompted by an economic motive in giving
up his law practice to accept public office. He
did so against the remonstrances of his friends, whose
predictions that what he would get out of it for himself
would be calumny, persecution, and loss of fortune,
were all fully verified; but he possessed a nature
which found its happiness in bringing high ideals
to grand fulfillment, and in applying his powers to
that object he let everything else go. Hamilton’s
career is one of the greatest of those facts that baffle
attempts to reduce history to an exhibition of the
play of economic forces.