In periods like the present, when
knowledge is every day extending, and the habits and
thoughts of mankind are perpetually changing under
the influence of new discoveries, it is no easy matter
to throw ourselves back into a time in which for centuries
the European world grew upon a single type, in which
the forms of the father’s thoughts were the forms
of the son’s, and the late descendant was occupied
in treading into paths the footprints of his distant
ancestors. So absolutely has change become the
law of our present condition, that it is identified
with energy and moral health; to cease to change is
to lose place in the great race; and to pass away from
off the earth with the same convictions which we found
when we entered it, is to have missed the best object
for which we now seem to exist.
It has been, however, with the race
of men as it has been with the planet which they inhabit.
As we look back over history, we see times of change
and progress alternating with other times when life
and thought have settled into permanent forms; when
mankind, as if by common consent, have ceased to seek
for increase of knowledge, and, contented with what
they possess, have endeavoured to make use of it for
purposes of moral cultivation. Such was the condition
of the Greeks through many ages before the Persian
war; such was that of the Romans till the world revenged
itself upon its conquerors by the introduction among
them of the habits of the conquered; and such again
became the condition of Europe when the Northern nations
grafted the religion and the laws of the Western empire
on their own hardy natures, and shaped out that wonderful
spiritual and political organisation which remained
unshaken for a thousand years.
The aspirant after sanctity in the
fifteenth century of the Christian era found a model
which he could imitate in detail in the saint of the
fifth. The gentleman at the court of Edward IV.
or Charles of Burgundy could imagine no nobler type
of heroism than he found in the stories of King Arthur’s
knights. The forms of life had become more elaborate the
surface of it more polished but the life
itself remained essentially the same; it was the development
of the same conception of human excellence; just as
the last orders of Gothic architecture were the development
of the first, from which the idea had worked its way
till the force of it was exhausted.
A condition of things differing alike
both outwardly and inwardly from that into which a
happier fortune has introduced ourselves, is necessarily
obscure to us. In the alteration of our own character,
we have lost the key which would interpret the characters
of our fathers, and the great men even of our own
English history before the Reformation seem to us almost
like the fossil skeletons of another order of beings.
Some broad conclusions as to what they were are at
least possible to us, however; and we are able to
determine, with tolerable certainty, the social condition
of the people of this country, such as it was before
the movements of the sixteenth century, and during
the process of those movements.
The extent of the population can only
be rudely conjectured. A rough census was taken
at the time of the Armada, when it was found to be
something under five millions; but anterior to this
I can find no authority on which I can rely with any
sort of confidence. It is my impression, however,
from a number of reasons each in itself
insignificant, but which taken together leave little
doubt upon my mind that it had attained
that number by a growth so slow as to be scarcely
perceptible, and had nearly approached to it many
generations before. Simon Fish, in The Supplication
of Beggars, says that the number of households
in England in 1531 was 520,000. His calculation
is of the most random kind; for he rates the number
of parishes at 52,000, with ten households on an average
in each parish. A mistake so preposterous respecting
the number of parishes shows the great ignorance of
educated men upon the subject. The ten households
in each parish may, probably (in some parts of the
country), have been a correct computation; but this
tells us little with respect to the aggregate numbers,
for the households were very large the farmers,
and the gentlemen also, usually having all the persons
whom they employed residing under their own roof.
Neither from this, therefore, nor from any other positive
statement which I have seen, can I gather any conclusion
that may be depended upon. But when we remember
the exceeding slowness with which the population multiplied
in a time in which we can accurately measure it that
is to say, from 1588 to the opening of the last century under
circumstances in every way more favourable to an increase,
I think we may assume that the increase was not so
great between 1500 and 1588, and that, previous to
1500, it did not more than keep pace with the waste
from civil and foreign war. The causes, indeed,
were wholly wanting which lead to a rapid growth of
numbers. Numbers now increase with the increase
of employment and with the facilities which are provided
by the modern system of labour for the establishment
of independent households. At present, any able-bodied
unskilled labourer earns, as soon as he has arrived
at man’s estate, as large an amount of wages
as he will earn at any subsequent time; and having
no connection with his employer beyond the receiving
the due amount of weekly money from him, and thinking
himself as well able to marry as he is likely to be,
he takes a wife, and is usually the father of a family
before he is thirty. Before the Reformation, not
only were early marriages determinately discouraged,
but the opportunity for them did not exist. A
labourer living in a cottage by himself was a rare
exception to the rule; and the work of the field was
performed generally, as it now is in the large farms
in America and Australia, by servants who lived in
the families of the squire or the farmer, and who,
while in that position, commonly remained single,
and married only when by prudence they had saved a
sufficient sum to enable them to enter some other position.
Checked by circumstances of this kind,
population would necessarily remain almost stationary,
and a tendency to an increase was not of itself regarded
by the statesmen of the day as any matter for congratulation
or as any evidence of national prosperity. Not
an increase of population, which would facilitate
production and beat down wages by competition, but
the increase of the commonwealth, the sound and healthy
maintenance of the population already existing, were
the chief objects which the government proposed to
itself; and although Henry VIII. carefully nursed his
manufactures, there is sufficient proof in the grounds
alleged for the measures to which he resorted, that
there was little redundancy of occupation.
In a statute, for instance, for the
encouragement of the linen manufactures, it is said
that “The King’s Highness, calling
to his most blessed remembrance the great number of
idle people daily increasing throughout this his Realm,
supposeth that one great cause thereof is by the continued
bringing into the same the great number of wares and
merchandise made, and brought out and from, the parts
beyond the sea into this his Realm, ready wrought
by manual occupation; amongst the which wares one kind
of merchandise in great quantity, which is linen cloth
of divers sorts made in divers countries beyond the
sea, is daily conveyed into this Realm; which great
quantity of linen cloth so brought is consumed and
spent within the same; by reason whereof not only
the said strange countries where the said linen cloth
is made, by the policy and industry of making and vending
the same are greatly enriched; and a marvellous great
number of their people, men, women, and children,
are set on work and occupation, and kept from idleness,
to the great furtherance and advancement of their
commonwealth; but also contrariwise the inhabitants
and subjects of this Realm, for lack of like policy
and industry, are compelled to buy all or most part
of the linen cloth consumed in the same, amounting
to inestimable sums of money. And also the people
of this Realm, as well men as women, which should
and might be set on work, by exercise of like policy
and craft of spinning, weaving, and making of cloth,
lies now in idleness and otiosity, to the high displeasure
of Almighty God, great diminution of the King’s
people, and extreme ruin, decay, and impoverishment
of this Realm. Therefore, for reformation of
these things, the King’s most Royal Majesty
intending, like a most virtuous Prince, to provide
remedy in the premises; nothing so much coveting as
the increase of the Commonwealth of this his Realm,
with also the virtuous exercise of his most loving
subjects and people, and to avoid that most abominable
sin of idleness out of the Realm, hath, by the advice
and consent of his Lords and Commons in Parliament
assembled, ordained and enacted that every person occupying
land for tillage, shall for every sixty acres which
he hath under the plough, sow one quarter of an acre
in flax or hemp.”
This Act was designed immediately
to keep the wives and children of the poor in work
in their own houses; but it leaves no doubt that
manufactures in England had not of themselves that
tendency to self-development which would encourage
an enlarging population. The woollen manufactures
similarly appear, from the many statutes upon them,
to have been vigorous at a fixed level, but to have
shown no tendency to rise beyond that level.
With a fixed market and a fixed demand, production
continued uniform.
A few years subsequent, indeed, to
the passing of the Act which I have quoted, a very
curious complaint is entered in the statute book, from
the surface of which we should gather, that so far
from increasing, manufactures had alarmingly declined.
The fact mentioned may bear another meaning, and a
meaning far more favourable to the state of the country;
although, if such a phenomenon were to occur at the
present time, it could admit of but one interpretation.
In the 18th and 19th of the 32nd of Henry VIII., all
the important towns in England, from the Tweed to the
Land’s End, are stated, one by one, to have
fallen into serious decay. Usually when we meet
with language of this kind, we suppose it to mean nothing
more than an awakening to the consciousness of evils
which had long existed, and which had escaped notice
only because no one was alive to them. In the
present instance, however, the language was too strong
and too detailed to allow of this explanation; and
the great body of the English towns undoubtedly were
declining in wealth and in the number of their inhabitants.
“Divers and many beautiful houses of habitation,”
these statutes say, “built in tyme past within
their walls and liberties, now are fallen down and
decayed, and at this day remain unre-edified, and do
lie as desolate and vacant grounds, many of them nigh
adjoining to the High-streets, replenished with much
uncleanness and filth, with pits, sellers, and vaults
lying open and uncovered, to the great perill and
danger of the inhabitants and other the King’s
subjects passing by the same; and some houses be very
weak and feeble, ready to fall down, and therefore
dangerous to pass by, to the great decay and hinderance
of the said boroughs and towns."
At present, the decay of a town implies
the decay of the trade of the town; and the decay
of all towns simultaneously would imply a general collapse
of the trade of the whole country. Walled towns,
however, before the Reformation, existed for other
purposes than as the centre points of industry:
they existed for the protection of property and life:
and although it is not unlikely that the agitation
of the Reformation itself did to some degree interrupt
the occupation of the people, yet I believe that the
true account of the phenomenon which then so much disturbed
the parliament, is, that one of their purposes was
no longer required; the towns flagged for a time because
the country had become secure. The woollen manufacture
in Worcestershire was spreading into the open country,
and, doubtless, in other counties as well; and the
“beautiful houses” which had fallen into
decay, were those which, in the old times of insecurity,
had been occupied by wealthy merchants and tradesmen,
who were now enabled, by a strong and settled government,
to dispense with the shelter of locked gates and fortified
walls, and remove their residences to more convenient
situations. It was, in fact, the first symptom
of the impending social revolution. Two years
before the passing of this Act, the magnificent Hengrave
Hall, in Suffolk, had been completed by Sir Thomas
Kitson, “mercer of London," and Sir Thomas
Kitson was but one of many of the rising merchants
who were now able to root themselves on the land by
the side of the Norman nobility, first to rival, and
then slowly to displace them.
This mighty change, however, was long
in silent progress before it began to tell on the
institutions of the country. When city burghers
bought estates, the law insisted jealously on their
accepting with them all the feudal obligations.
Attempts to use the land as “a commodity”
were, as we shall presently see, angrily repressed;
while, again, in the majority of instances, such persons
endeavoured, as they do at present, to cover the recent
origin of their families by adopting the manners of
the nobles, instead of transferring the habits of
the towns to the parks and chases of the English counties.
The old English organisation maintained its full activity;
and the duties of property continued to be for another
century more considered than its rights.
Turning, then, to the tenure of land for
if we would understand the condition of the people,
it is to this point that our first attention must
be directed we find that through the many
complicated varieties of it there was one broad principle
which bore equally upon every class, that the land
of England must provide for the defence of England.
The feudal system, though practically modified, was
still the organising principle of the nation, and
the owner of land was bound to military service for
his country whenever occasion required. Further,
the land was to be so administered, that the accustomed
number of families supported by it should not be diminished,
and that the State should suffer no injury from the
carelessness or selfishness of the owners. Land
never was private property in that personal sense
of property in which we speak of a thing as our own,
with which we may do as we please; and in the administration
of estates, as indeed in the administration of all
property whatsoever, duty to the State was at all
times supposed to override private interest or inclination.
Even tradesmen, who took advantage of the fluctuations
of the market, were rebuked by parliament for “their
greedy and covetous minds,” “as more regarding
their own singular lucre and profit than the commonweal
of the Realm;" and although in an altered world,
neither industry nor enterprise will thrive except
under the stimulus of self-interest, we may admire
the confidence which in another age expected every
man to prefer the advantage of the community to his
own. All land was held upon a strictly military
principle. It was the representative of authority,
and the holder or the owner took rank in the army
of the State according to the nature of his connection
with it. It was first broadly divided among the
great nobility holding immediately under the crown,
who, above and beyond the ownership of their private
estates, were the Lords of the Fee throughout their
presidency, and possessed in right of it the services
of knights and gentlemen who held their manors under
them, and who followed their standard in war.
Under the lords of manors, again, small freeholds and
copyholds were held of various extent, often forty
shilling and twenty shilling value, tenanted by peasant
occupiers, who thus, on their own land, lived as free
Englishmen, maintaining by their own free labour themselves
and their families. There was thus a descending
scale of owners, each of whom possessed his separate
right, which the law guarded and none might violate;
yet no one of whom, again, was independent of an authority
higher than himself; and the entire body of the English
free possessors of the soil was interpenetrated by
a coherent organisation which converted them into a
perpetually subsisting army of soldiers. The extent
of land which was held by the petty freeholders was
very large, and the possession of it was jealously
treasured; the private estates of the nobles and gentlemen
were either cultivated by their own servants, or let
out, as at present, to free tenants; or (in earlier
times) were occupied by villains, a class who, without
being bondmen, were expected to furnish further services
than those of the field, services which were limited
by the law, and recognised by an outward ceremony,
a solemn oath and promise from the villain to his lord.
Villanage, in the reign of Henry VIII., had practically
ceased. The name of it last appears upon the
statute book in the early years of the reign of Richard
II., when the disputes between villains and their liege
lords on their relative rights had furnished matter
for cumbrous lawsuits, and by general consent the
relation had merged of itself into a more liberal form.
Thus serfdom had merged or was rapidly merging into
free servitude; but it did not so merge that labouring
men, if they pleased, were allowed to live in idleness.
Every man was regimented somewhere; and although the
peasantry, when at full age, were allowed, under restrictions,
their own choice of masters, yet the restrictions
both on masters and servants were so severe as to
prevent either from taking advantage of the necessities
of the other, or from terminating through caprice
or levity, or for any insufficient reason, a connection
presumed to be permanent.
Through all these arrangements a single
aim is visible, that every man in England should have
his definite place and definite duty assigned to him,
and that no human being should be at liberty to lead
at his own pleasure an unaccountable existence.
The discipline of an army was transferred to the details
of social life, and it issued in a chivalrous perception
of the meaning of the word duty, and in the old characteristic
spirit of English loyalty.
From the regulations with respect
to land, a coarser advantage was also derived, of
a kind which at the present time will be effectively
appreciated. It is a common matter of dispute
whether landed estates should be large or small; whether
it is better that the land should be divided among
small proprietors, cultivating their own ground, or
that it should follow its present tendency, and be
shared by a limited and constantly diminishing number
of wealthy landlords. The advocates for a peasant
proprietary tell us truly, that a landed monopoly is
dangerous; that the possession of a spot of ground,
though it be but a few acres, is the best security
for loyalty, giving the state a pledge for its owner,
and creating in the body of the nation a free, vigorous,
and manly spirit. The advocates for the large
estates tell us, that the masses are too ill-educated
to be trusted with independence; that without authority
over them, these small proprietors become wasteful,
careless, improvident; that the free spirit becomes
a democratic and dangerous spirit; and finally, that
the resources of the land cannot properly be brought
out by men without capital to cultivate it. Either
theory is plausible. The advocates of both can
support their arguments with an appeal to experience;
and the verdict of fact has not as yet been pronounced
emphatically.
The problem will be resolved in the
future history of this country. It was also nobly
and skilfully resolved in the past. The knights
and nobles retained the authority and power which
was attached to the lordships of the fees. They
retained extensive estates in their own hands or in
the occupation of their immediate tenants; but the
large proportion of the lands was granted out by them
to smaller owners, and the expenditure of their own
incomes in the wages and maintenance of their vast
retinues left but a small margin for indulgence in
luxuries. The necessities of their position obliged
them to regard their property rather as a revenue to
be administered in trust, than as “a fortune”
to be expended in indulgence. Before the Reformation,
while the differences of social degree were enormous,
the differences in habits of life were comparatively
slight, and the practice of men in these things was
curiously the reverse of our own. Dress, which
now scarcely suffices to distinguish the master from
his servant, was then the symbol of rank, prescribed
by statute to the various orders of society as strictly
as the regimental uniform to officers and privates;
diet also was prescribed, and with equal strictness;
but the diet of the nobleman was ordered down to a
level which was then within the reach of the poorest
labourer. In 1336, the following law was enacted
by the Parliament of Edward III.: “Whereas,
heretofore through the excessive and over-many sorts
of costly meats which the people of this Realm have
used more than elsewhere, many mischiefs have happened
to the people of this Realm for the great
men by these excesses have been sore grieved; and
the lesser people, who only endeavour to imitate the
great ones in such sort of meats, are much impoverished,
whereby they are not able to aid themselves, nor their
liege lord, in time of need, as they ought; and many
other evils have happened, as well to their souls as
their bodies our Lord the King, desiring
the common profit as well of the great men as the common
people of his Realm, and considering the evils, grievances,
and mischiefs aforesaid, by the common assent of the
prelates, earls, barons, and other nobles of his said
Realm, and of the commons of the same Realm, hath
ordained and established that no man, of what estate
or condition soever he be, shall cause himself to
be served, in his house or elsewhere, at dinner, meal,
or supper, or at any other time, with more than two
courses, and each mess of two sorts of victuals at
the utmost, be it of flesh or fish, with the common
sorts of pottage, without sauce or any other sorts
of victuals. And if any man choose to have sauce
for his mess, he may, provided it be not made at great
cost; and if fish or flesh be to be mixed therein,
it shall be of two sorts only at the utmost, either
fish or flesh, and shall stand instead of a mess,
except only on the principal feasts of the year, on
which days every man may be served with three courses
at the utmost, after the manner aforesaid.”
Sumptuary laws are among the exploded
fallacies which we have outgrown, and we smile at
the unwisdom which could expect to regulate private
habits and manners by statute. Yet some statutes
may be of moral authority when they cannot be actually
enforced, and may have been regarded, even at the time
at which they were issued, rather as an authoritative
declaration of what wise and good men considered to
be right, than as laws to which obedience could be
compelled. This act, at any rate, witnesses to
what was then thought to be right by “the great
persons” of the English realm; and when great
persons will submit themselves of their free will to
regulations which restrict their private indulgence,
they are in little danger of disloyalty from those
whom fortune has placed below them.
Such is one aspect of these old arrangements;
it is unnecessary to say that with these, as with
all other institutions created and worked by human
beings, the picture admits of being reversed.
When by the accident of birth men are placed in a
position of authority, no care in their training will
prevent it from falling often to singularly unfit persons.
The command of a permanent military force was a temptation
to ambition, to avarice, or hatred, to the indulgence
of private piqués and jealousies, to political
discontent on private and personal grounds. A
combination of three or four of the leading nobles
was sufficient, when an incapable prince sate on the
throne, to effect a revolution; and the rival claims
of the houses of York and Lancaster to the crown,
took the form of a war unequalled in history for its
fierce and determined malignancy, the whole nation
tearing itself in pieces in a quarrel in which no
principle was at stake, and no national object was
to be gained. A more terrible misfortune never
befel either this or any other country, and it was
made possible only in virtue of that loyalty with
which the people followed the standard, through good
and evil, of their feudal superiors. It is still
a question, however, whether the good or the evil
of the system predominated; and the answer to such
question is the more difficult because we have no criterion
by which, in these matters, degrees of good and evil
admit of being measured. Arising out of the character
of the nation, it reflected this character in all its
peculiarities; and there is something truly noble in
the coherence of society upon principles of fidelity.
Fidelity of man to man is among the rarest excellences
of humanity, and we can tolerate large evils which
arise out of such a cause. Under the feudal system
men were held together by oaths, free acknowledgments,
and reciprocal obligations, entered into by all ranks,
high and low, binding servants to their masters, as
well as nobles to their kings; and in the frequent
forms of the language in which the oaths were sworn
we cannot choose but see that we have lost something
in exchanging these ties for the harsher connecting
links of mutual self-interest.
“When a freeman shall do fealty
to his lord,” the statute says, “he shall
hold his right hand upon the book, and shall say thus: Hear
you, my lord, that I shall be to you both faithful
and true, and shall owe my faith to you for the land
that I hold, and lawfully shall do such customs and
services as my duty is to you, at the times assigned,
so help me God and all his saints.”
“The villain,” also, “when
he shall do fealty to his lord, shall hold his right
hand over the book, and shall say: Hear
you, my lord, that I from this day forth unto you
shall be true and faithful, and shall owe you fealty
for the land which I hold of you in villanage; and
that no evil or damage will I see concerning you,
but I will defend and warn you to my power. So
help me God and all his saints."
Again, in the distribution of the
produce of land, men dealt fairly and justly with
each other; and in the material condition of the bulk
of the people there is a fair evidence that the system
worked efficiently and well. It worked well for
the support of a sturdy high-hearted race, sound in
body and fierce in spirit, and furnished with thews
and sinews which, under the stimulus of those “great
shins of beef," their common diet, were the wonder
of the age. “What comyn folke in all this
world,” says a state paper in 1515 “may
compare with the comyns of England in riches, freedom,
liberty, welfare, and all prosperity? What comyn
folke is so mighty, so strong in the felde, as the
comyns of England?” The relative numbers of
the French and English armies which fought at Cressy
and Agincourt may have been exaggerated, but no allowance
for exaggeration will effect the greatness of those
exploits; and in stories of authentic actions under
Henry VIII., where the accuracy of the account is undeniable,
no disparity of force made Englishmen shrink from
enemies wherever they could meet them. Again
and again a few thousands of them carried dismay into
the heart of France. Four hundred adventurers,
vagabond apprentices, from London, who formed
a volunteer corps in the Calais garrison, were for
years the terror of Normandy. In the very frolic
of conscious power they fought and plundered, without
pay, without reward, except what they could win for
themselves; and when they fell at last they fell only
when surrounded by six times their number, and were
cut to pieces in careless desperation. Invariably,
by friend and enemy alike, the English are described
as the fiercest people in all Europe (the English wild
beasts, Benvenuto Cellini calls them); and this great
physical power they owed to the profuse abundance
in which they lived, and to the soldier’s training
in which every man of them was bred from childhood.
The state of the working classes can, however, be
more certainly determined by a comparison of their
wages with the prices of food. Both were regulated,
so far as regulation was possible, by act of parliament,
and we have therefore data of the clearest kind by
which to judge. The majority of agricultural labourers
lived, as I have said, in the houses of their employers;
this, however, was not the case with all, and if we
can satisfy ourselves as to the rate at which those
among the poor were able to live who had cottages of
their own, we may be assured that the rest did not
live worse at their masters’ tables.
Wheat, the price of which necessarily
varied, averaged in the middle of the fourteenth century
tenpence the bushel; barley averaging at the same
time three shillings the quarter. With wheat the
fluctuation was excessive; a table of its possible
variations describes it as ranging from eighteenpence
the quarter to twenty shillings; the average, however,
being six and eightpence. When the price was above
this sum, the merchants might import to bring it down;
when it was below this price the farmers were allowed
to export to the foreign markets. The same scale,
with a scarcely appreciable tendency to rise, continued
to hold until the disturbance in the value of the
currency. In the twelve years from 1551 to 1562,
although once before harvest wheat rose to the extraordinary
price of forty-five shillings a quarter, it fell immediately
after to five shillings and four. Six and eightpence
continued to be considered in parliament as the average;
and on the whole it seems to have been maintained
for that time with little variation.
Beef and pork were a halfpenny a pound mutton
was three farthings. They were fixed at these
prices by the 3rd of the 24th of Hen. VIII.
But the act was unpopular both with buyers and with
sellers. The old practice had been to sell in
the gross, and under that arrangement the rates had
been generally lower. Stow says, “It
was this year enacted that butchers should sell their
beef and mutton by weight beef for a halfpenny
the pound, and mutton for three farthings; which being
devised for the great commodity of the realm (as it
was thought), hath proved far otherwise: for
at that time fat oxen were sold for six and twenty
shillings and eightpence the piece; fat wethers for
three shillings and fourpence the piece; fat calves
at a like price; and fat lambs for twelvepence.
The butchers of London sold penny pieces of beef for
the relief of the poor every piece two
pound and a half, sometimes three pound for a penny;
and thirteen and sometimes fourteen of these pieces
for twelvepence; mutton eightpence the quarter, and
an hundred weight of beef for four shillings and eightpence.”
The act was repealed in consequence of the complaints
against it, but the prices never fell again to
what they had been, although beef sold in the gross
could still be had for a halfpenny a pound in 1570.
Other articles of food were in the same proportion.
The best pig or goose in a country market could be
bought for fourpence; a good capon for threepence
or fourpence; a chicken for a penny; a hen for twopence.
Strong beer, such as we now buy for
eighteenpence a gallon, was then a penny a gallon;
and table-beer less than a halfpenny. French and
German wines were eightpence the gallon. Spanish
and Portuguese wines a shilling. This was the
highest price at which the best wines might be sold;
and if there was any fault in quality or quantity,
the dealers forfeited four times the amount. Rent,
another important consideration, cannot be fixed so
accurately, for parliament did not interfere with it.
Here, however, we are not without very tolerable information.
“My father,” says Latimer, “was
a yeoman, and had no lands of his own; only he had
a farm of three or four pounds by the year
at the uttermost, and hereupon he tilled so much as
kept half-a-dozen men. He had walk for a hundred
sheep, and my mother milked thirty kine. He was
able, and did find the king a harness with himself
and his horse. I remember that I buckled on his
harness when he went to Blackheath field. He kept
me to school, or else I had not been able to have
preached before the King’s Majesty now.
He married my sisters with five pounds, or twenty
nobles, each, having brought them up in godliness
and fear of God. He kept hospitality for his poor
neighbours, and some alms he gave to the poor; and
all this he did of the said farm.” If “three
or four pounds at the uttermost” was the rent
of a farm yielding such results, the rent of labourers’
cottages is not likely to have been considerable.
Some uncertainty is unavoidable in
all calculations of the present nature; yet, after
making the utmost allowances for errors, we may conclude
from such a table of prices that a penny, in terms
of the labourer’s necessities, must have been
nearly equal in the reign of Henry VIII. to the present
shilling. For a penny, at the time of which I
write, the labourer could buy as much bread, beef,
beer, and wine he could do as much towards
finding lodging for himself and his family as
the labourer of the nineteenth century can for a shilling.
I do not see that this admits of question. Turning,
then, to the table of wages, it will be easy to ascertain
his position. By the 3rd of the 6th of Henry VIII.
it was enacted that master carpenters, masons, bricklayers,
tylers, plumbers, glaziers, joiners, and other employers
of such skilled workmen, should give to each of their
journeymen, if no meat or drink was allowed, sixpence
a day for the half year, fivepence a day for the other
half; or fivepence-halfpenny for the yearly average.
The common labourers were to receive fourpence a day
for half the year, for the remaining half, threepence.
In the harvest months they were allowed to work by
the piece, and might earn considerably more; so
that, in fact (and this was the rate at which their
wages were usually estimated), the day labourer, if
in full employment, received on an average fourpence
a day for the whole year. Allowing a deduction
of one day in a fortnight for a saint’s day or
a holiday, he received, therefore, steadily and regularly,
if well conducted, an equivalent of something near
to twenty shillings a week, the wages at present paid
in English colonies: and this is far from being
a full account of his advantages. Except in rare
instances, the agricultural labourer held land in
connection with his house, while in most parishes,
if not in all, there were large ranges of common and
unenclosed forest land, which furnished his fuel to
him gratis, where pigs might range, and ducks and
geese; where, if he could afford a cow, he was in no
danger of being unable to feed it; and so important
was this privilege considered, that when the commons
began to be largely enclosed, parliament insisted that
the working man should not be without some piece of
ground on which he could employ his own and his family’s
industry. By the 7th of the 31st of Elizabeth,
it was ordered that no cottage should be built for
residence without four acres of land at lowest being
attached to it for the sole use of the occupants of
such cottage.
It will, perhaps, be supposed that
such comparative prosperity of labour was the result
of the condition of the market in which it was sold,
that the demand for labour was large and the supply
limited, and that the state of England in the sixteenth
century was analogous to that of Australia or Canada
at the present time. And so long as we confine
our view to the question of wages alone, it is undoubted
that legislation was in favour of the employer.
The Wages Act of Henry VIII. was unpopular with the
labourers, and was held to deprive them of an opportunity
of making better terms for themselves. But we
shall fall into extreme error if we translate into
the language of modern political economy the social
features of a state of things which in no way correspond
to our own. There was this essential difference,
that labour was not looked upon as a market commodity;
the government (whether wisely or not, I do not presume
to determine) attempting to portion out the rights
of the various classes of society by the rule, not
of economy, but of equity. Statesmen did not care
for the accumulation of capital; they desired to see
the physical well-being of all classes of the commonwealth
maintained at the highest degree which the producing
power of the country admitted; and population and
production remaining stationary, they were able to
do it. This was their object, and they were supported
in it by a powerful and efficient majority of the
nation. On the one side parliament interfered
to protect employers against their labourers; but
it was equally determined that employers should not
be allowed to abuse their opportunities; and this
directly appears from the 4th of the 5th of Elizabeth,
by which, on the most trifling appearance of a depreciation
in the currency, it was declared that the labouring
man could no longer live on the wages assigned to him
by the act of Henry; and a sliding scale was instituted
by which, for the future, wages should be adjusted
to the price of food.
The same conclusion may be gathered
also, indirectly, from other acts, interfering imperiously
with the rights of property where a disposition showed
itself to exercise them selfishly. The city merchants,
as I have said, were becoming landowners; and some
of them attempted to apply the rules of trade to the
management of landed estates. While wages were
ruled so high, it answered better as a speculation
to convert arable land into pasture; but the law immediately
stepped in to prevent a proceeding which it regarded
as petty treason to the commonwealth. Self-protection
is the first law of life; and the country relying
for its defence on an able-bodied population, evenly
distributed, ready at any moment to be called into
action, either against foreign invasion or civil disturbance,
it could not permit the owners of land to pursue for
their own benefit a course of action which threatened
to weaken its garrisons. It is not often that
we are able to test the wisdom of legislation by specific
results so clearly as in the present instance.
The first attempts of the kind which I have described
were made in the Isle of Wight, early in the reign
of Henry VII. Lying so directly exposed to attacks
from France, the Isle of Wight was a place which it
was peculiarly important to keep in a state of defence,
and the following act was therefore the consequence:
“Forasmuch as it is to the surety
of the Realm of England that the Isle of Wight, in
the county of Southampton, be well inhabited with English
people, for the defence as well of our antient enemies
of the Realm of France as of other parties; the which
Isle is late decayed of people by reason that many
towns and villages have been let down, and the fields
dyked and made pasture for beasts and cattle, and
also many dwelling-places, farms, and farmholds have
of late time been used to be taken into one man’s
hold and hands, that of old time were wont to be in
many several persons’ holds and hands, and many
several households kept in them; and thereby much people
multiplied, and the same Isle thereby well inhabited,
which now, by the occasion aforesaid, is desolate
and not inhabited, but occupied with beasts and cattle,
so that if hasty remedy be not provided, that Isle
cannot long be kept and defended, but open and ready
to the hands of the king’s enemies, which God
forbid. For remedy hereof, it is ordained and
enacted that no manner of person, of what estate,
degree, or condition soever, shall take any several
farms more than one, whereof the yearly value shall
not exceed the sum of ten marks; and if any several
leases afore this time have been made to any person
or persons of divers and sundry farmholds, whereof
the yearly value shall exceed that sum, then the said
person or persons shall choose one farmhold at his
pleasure, and the remnant of his leases shall be utterly
void."
An act, tyrannical in form, was singularly
justified by its consequences. The farms were
rebuilt, the lands reploughed, the island repeopled;
and in 1546, when a French army of sixty thousand
men attempted to effect a landing at St. Helen’s,
they were defeated and driven off by the militia of
the island and a few levies transported from Hampshire
and the adjoining counties. The money-making spirit,
however, lay too deep to be checked so readily.
The trading classes were growing rich under the strong
rule of the Tudors. Increasing numbers of them
were buying or renting land; and the symptoms complained
of broke out in the following reign in many parts of
England. They could not choose but break out indeed;
for they were the outward marks of a vital change,
which was undermining the feudal constitution, and
would by and bye revolutionise and destroy it.
Such symptoms it was impossible to extinguish; but
the government wrestled long and powerfully to hold
down the new spirit; and they fought against it successfully,
till the old order of things had finished its work,
and the time was come for it to depart. By the
1st of the 7th of Henry VIII., the laws of feudal
tenure were put in force against the landed traders.
Wherever lands were converted from tillage to pasture,
the lords of the fee had authority to seize half of
all profits until the farm-buildings were reconstructed.
If the immediate lord did not do his duty, the lord
next above him was to do it; and the evil still increasing,
the act, twenty years later, was extended further,
and the king had power to seize. Nor was this
all. Sheep-farming had become an integral branch
of business; and falling into the hands of men who
understood each other, it had been made a monopoly,
affecting seriously the prices of wool and mutton.
Stronger measures were therefore now taken, and the
class to which the offenders belonged was especially
pointed out by parliament.
“Whereas,” says the 13th
of the 25th of Henry VIII., “divers and sundry
persons of the king’s subjects of this Realm,
to whom God of his goodness hath disposed great plenty
and abundance of moveable substance, now of late,
within few years, have daily studied, practised, and
invented ways and means how they might accumulate
and gather together into few hands, as well great
multitude of farms as great plenty of cattle, and in
especial, sheep, putting such lands as they can get
to pasture and not to tillage; whereby they have not
only pulled down churches and towns and enhanced the
old rates of the rents of the possessions of this Realm,
or else brought it to such excessive fines that no
poor man is able to meddle with it, but also have
raised and enhanced the prices of all manner of corn,
cattle, wool, pigs, geese, hens, chickens, eggs, and
such other commodities, almost double above the prices
which hath been accustomed, by reason whereof a marvellous
multitude of the poor people of this realm be not able
to provide meat, drink, and clothes necessary for
themselves, their wives, and children, but be so discouraged
with misery and poverty, that they fall daily to theft,
robbery, and other inconveniences, or pitifully die
for hunger and cold; and it is thought by the king’s
humble and loving subjects, that one of the greatest
occasions that moveth those greedy and covetous people
so to accumulate and keep in their hands such great
portions and parts of the lands of this Realm from
the occupying of the poor husbandmen, and so to use
it in pasture and not in tillage, is the great profit
that cometh of sheep which be now come into a few persons’
hands, in respect of the whole number of the king’s
subjects; it is hereby enacted, that no person shall
have or keep on lands not their own inheritance more
than 2000 sheep; that no person shall occupy more than
two farms; and that the 19th of the 4th of Henry VII.,
and those other acts obliging the lords of the fees
to do their duty, shall be re-enacted and enforced."
By these measures the money-making
spirit was for a time driven back, and the country
resumed its natural course. I am not concerned
to defend the economic wisdom of such proceedings;
but they prove, I think, conclusively, that the labouring
classes owed their advantages not to the condition
of the labour market, but to the care of the state;
and that when the state relaxed its supervision, or
failed to enforce its regulations, the labourers being
left to the market chances, sank instantly in the unequal
struggle with capital.
The government, however, remained
strong enough to hold its ground (except during the
discreditable interlude of the reign of Edward VI.)
for the first three quarters of the century; and until
that time the working classes of this country remained
in a condition more than prosperous. They enjoyed
an abundance far beyond what in general falls to the
lot of that order in long-settled countries; incomparably
beyond what the same class were enjoying at that very
time in Germany or France. The laws secured them;
and that the laws were put in force we have the direct
evidence of successive acts of the legislature justifying
the general policy by its success: and we have
also the indirect evidence of the contented loyalty
of the great body of the people at a time when, if
they had been discontented, they held in their own
hands the means of asserting what the law acknowledged
to be their right. The government had no power
to compel submission to injustice, as was proved by
the fate of an attempt to levy a “benevolence”
by force, in 1525. The people resisted with a
determination against which the crown commissioners
were unable to contend, and the scheme ended with
an acknowledgment of fault by Henry, who retired with
a good grace from an impossible position. If
the peasantry had been suffering under any real grievances
we should not have failed to have heard of them when
the religious rebellions furnished so fair an opportunity
to press those grievances forward. Complaint
was loud enough when complaint was just, under the
Somerset protectorate.
The incomes of the great nobles cannot
be determined, for they varied probably as much as
they vary now. Under Henry IV. the average income
of an earl was estimated at L2000 a year. Under
Henry VIII. the great Duke of Buckingham, the wealthiest
English peer, had L6000. And the income of the
Archbishop of Canterbury was rated at the same amount.
But the establishments of such men were enormous;
their ordinary retinues in time of peace consisting
of many hundred persons; and in war, when the duties
of a nobleman called him to the field, although in
theory his followers were paid by the crown, yet the
grants of parliament were on so small a scale that
the theory was seldom converted into fact, and a large
share of the expenses was paid often out of private
purses. The Duke of Norfolk, in the Scotch war
of 1523, declared (not complaining of it, but merely
as a reason why he should receive support) that he
had spent all his private means upon the army; and
in the sequel of this history we shall find repeated
instances of knights and gentlemen voluntarily ruining
themselves in the service of their country. The
people, not universally, but generally, were animated
by a true spirit of sacrifice; by a true conviction
that they were bound to think first of England, and
only next of themselves; and unless we can bring ourselves
to understand this, we shall never understand what
England was under the reigns of the Plantagenets and
Tudors. The expenses of the court under Henry
VII. were a little over L14,000 a year, out of which
were defrayed the whole cost of the king’s establishment,
the expenses of entertaining foreign ambassadors,
the wages and maintenance of the yeomen of the guard,
the retinues of servants, and all necessary outlay
not incurred for public business. Under Henry
VIII., of whose extravagance we have heard so much,
and whose court was the most magnificent in the world,
these expenses were L19,894 16d., a small sum
when compared with the present cost of the royal establishment,
even if we adopt the relative estimate of twelve to
one, and suppose it equal to L240,000 a year of our
money. But indeed it was not equal to L240,000;
for, although the proportion held in articles of common
consumption, articles of luxury were very dear indeed.
Passing down from the king and his
nobles, to the body of the people, we find that the
income qualifying a country gentleman to be justice
of the peace was L20 a year, and if he did his
duty, his office was no sinecure. We remember
Justice Shallow and his clerk Davy, with his novel
theory of magisterial law; and Shallow’s broad
features have so English a cast about them, that we
may believe there were many such, and that the duty
was not always very excellently done. But the
Justice Shallows were not allowed to repose upon their
dignity. The justice of the peace was required
not only to take cognisance of open offences, but to
keep surveillance over all persons within his district,
and over himself in his own turn there was a surveillance
no less sharp, and penalties for neglect prompt and
peremptory. Four times a year he was to make proclamation
of his duty, and exhort all persons to complain against
him who had occasion.
Twenty pounds a year, and heavy duties
to do for it, represented the condition of the squire
of the parish. By the 2nd of the 2nd of Henry
V., “the wages” of a parish priest were
limited to L5 6d., except in cases where there
was special licence from the bishop, when they might
be raised as high as L6. Priests were probably
something better off under Henry VIII., but the statute
remained in force, and marks an approach at least
to their ordinary salary. The priest had enough,
being unmarried, to supply him in comfort with the
necessaries of life. The squire had enough to
provide moderate abundance for himself and his family.
Neither priest nor squire was able to establish any
steep difference in outward advantages between himself
and the commons among whom he lived.
The habits of all classes were open,
free, and liberal. There are two expressions
corresponding one to the other, which we frequently
meet with in old writings, and which are used as a
kind of index, marking whether the condition of things
was or was not what it ought to be. We read of
“merry England;” when England
was not merry, things were not going well with it.
We hear of “the glory of hospitality,”
England’s pre-eminent boast,-by the rules of
which all tables, from the table of the twenty-shilling
freeholder to the table in the baron’s hall
and abbey refectory, were open at the dinner hour
to all comers, without stint or reserve, or question
asked: to every man, according to his degree,
who chose to ask for it there was free fee and free
lodging; bread, beef, and beer for his dinner; for
his lodging, perhaps, only a mat of rushes in a spare
corner of the hall, with a billet of wood for a pillow,
but freely offered and freely taken, the guest probably
faring much as his host fared, neither worse nor better.
There was little fear of an abuse of such licence,
for suspicious characters had no leave to wander at
pleasure; and for any man found at large and unable
to give a sufficient account of himself, there were
the ever-ready parish stocks or town gaol. The
“glory of hospitality” lasted far down
into Elizabeth’s time; and then, as Camden says,
“came in great bravery of building, to the marvellous
beautifying of the realm, but to the decay”
of what he valued more.
In such frank style the people lived,
hating three things with all their hearts: idleness,
want, and cowardice; and for the rest carrying their
hearts high, and having their hands full. The
hour of rising, winter and summer, was four o’clock,
with breakfast at five, after which the labourers
went to work and the gentlemen to business, of which
they had no little. In the country every unknown
face was challenged and examined if the
account given was insufficient, he was brought before
the justice; if the village shopkeeper sold bad wares,
if the village cobbler made “unhonest”
shoes, if servants and masters quarrelled, all was
to be looked to by the justice; there was no fear
lest time should hang heavy with him. At twelve
he dined; after dinner he went hunting, or to his farm
or to what he pleased. It was a life unrefined,
perhaps, but coloured with a broad, rosy, English
health.
Of the education of noblemen and gentlemen
we have contradictory accounts, as might be expected.
The universities were well filled, by the sons of
yeomen chiefly. The cost of supporting them at
the colleges was little, and wealthy men took a pride
in helping forward any boys of promise. It seems
clear also, as the Reformation drew nearer, while the
clergy were sinking lower and lower, a marked change
for the better became perceptible in a portion at
least of the laity. The more old-fashioned of
the higher ranks were slow in moving; for as late
as the reign of Edward VI. there were peers of
parliament unable to read; but on the whole, the invention
of printing, and the general ferment which was commencing
all over the world, had produced marked effects in
all classes. Henry VIII. himself spoke four languages,
and was well read in theology and history; and the
high accomplishments of More and Sir T. Elliott, of
Wyatt and Cromwell, were but the extreme expression
of a temper which was rapidly spreading, and which
gave occasion, among other things to the following
reflection in Erasmus. “Oh, strange vicissitudes
of human things,” exclaims he. “Heretofore
the heart of learning was among such as professed
religion. Now, while they for the most part give
themselves up, ventri luxui pecuniaeque, the
love of learning is gone from them to secular princes,
the court and the nobility. May we not justly
be ashamed of ourselves? The feasts of priests
and divines are drowned in wine, are filled with scurrilous
jests, sound with intemperate noise and tumult, flow
with spiteful slanders and defamation of others; while
at princes’ tables modest disputations are held
concerning things which make for learning and piety.”
A letter to Thomas Cromwell from his
son’s tutor will not be without interest on
this subject; Cromwell was likely to have been unusually
careful in his children’s training, and we need
not suppose that all boys were brought up as prudently.
Sir Peter Carew, for instance, being a boy at about
the same time, and giving trouble at the High School
at Exeter, was led home to his father’s house
at Ottery, coupled between two foxhounds. Yet
the education of Gregory Cromwell is probably not far
above what many young men of the middle and higher
ranks were beginning to receive. Henry Dowes
was the tutor’s name, beyond which fact I know
nothing of him. His letter is as follows:
“After that it pleased your
mastership to give me in charge, not only to give
diligent attendance upon Master Gregory, but also to
instruct him with good letters, honest manners, pastyme
of instruments, and such other qualities as should
be for him meet and convenient, pleaseth it you to
understand that for the accomplishment thereof I have
endeavoured myself by all ways possible to excogitate
how I might most profit him. In which behalf,
through his diligence, the success is such as I trust
shall be to your good contentation and pleasure, and
to his no small profit. But for cause the summer
was spent in the service of the wild gods, [and] it
is so much to be regarded after what fashion youth
is brought up, in which time that that is learned
for the most part will not be wholly forgotten in the
older years, I think it my duty to acertain your mastership
how he spendeth his time. And first after he
hath heard mass he taketh a lecture of a dialogue
of Erasmus’ Colloquies, called Pietas
Puerilis, wherein is described a very picture
of one that should be virtuously brought up; and for
cause it is so necessary for him, I do not only cause
him to read it over, but also to practise the precepts
of the same. After this he exerciseth his hand
in writing one or two hours, and readeth upon Fabyan’s
Chronicle as long. The residue of the day
he doth spend upon the lute and virginals.
When he rideth, as he doth very oft, I tell him by
the way some history of the Romans or the Greeks,
which I cause him to rehearse again in a tale.
For his recreation he useth to hawk and hunt and shoot
in his long bow, which frameth and succeedeth so well
with him that he seemeth to be thereunto given by
nature."
I have spoken of the organisation
of the country population, I have now to speak of
that of the towns, of the trading classes and manufacturing
classes, the regulations respecting which are no less
remarkable and no less illustrative of the national
character. If the tendency of trade to assume
at last a form of mere self-interest be irresistible,
if political economy represent the laws to which in
the end it is forced to submit itself, the nation
spared no efforts, either of art or policy, to defer
to the last moment the unwelcome conclusion.
The names and shadows linger about
London of certain ancient societies, the members of
which may still occasionally be seen in quaint gilt
barges pursuing their own difficult way among the
swarming steamers; when on certain days, the traditions
concerning which are fast dying out of memory, the
Fishmongers’ Company, the Goldsmiths’ Company,
the Mercers’ Company, make procession down the
river for civic feastings at Greenwich or Blackwall.
The stately tokens of ancient honour still belong to
them, and the remnants of ancient wealth and patronage
and power. Their charters may be read by curious
antiquaries, and the bills of fare of their ancient
entertainments. But for what purpose they were
called into being, what there was in these associations
of common trades to surround with gilded insignia,
and how they came to be possessed of broad lands and
church preferments, few people now care to think or
to inquire. Trade and traders have no dignity
any more in the eyes of any one, except what money
lends to them; and these outward symbols scarcely
rouse even a passing feeling of curiosity. And
yet these companies were once something more than names.
They are all which now remain of a vast organisation
which once penetrated the entire trading life of England an
organisation set on foot to realise that most necessary,
if most difficult, condition of commercial excellence
under which man should deal faithfully with his brother,
and all wares offered for sale, of whatever kind,
should honestly be what they pretend to be. I
spoke of the military principle which directed the
distribution and the arrangements of land. The
analogy will best explain a state of things in which
every occupation was treated as the division of an
army; regiments being quartered in every town, each
with its own self-elected officers, whose duty was
to exercise authority over all persons professing
the business to which they belonged; who were to see
that no person undertook to supply articles which
he had not been educated to manufacture; who were
to determine the prices at which such articles ought
justly to be sold; above all, who were to take care
that the common people really bought at shops and
stalls what they supposed themselves to be buying;
that cloth put up for sale was true cloth, of true
texture and full weight: that leather was sound
and well tanned; wine pure, measures honest; flour
unmixed with devil’s dust; who were
generally to look to it that in all contracts between
man and man for the supply of man’s necessities,
what we call honesty of dealing should be truly and
faithfully observed. An organisation for this
purpose did once really exist in England, really
trying to do the work which it was intended to do,
as half the pages of our early statutes witness.
In London, as the metropolis, a central council sate
for every branch of trade, and this council was in
communication with the Chancellor and the Crown.
It was composed of the highest and most respectable
members of the profession, and its office was to determine
prices, fix wages, arrange the rules of apprenticeship,
and discuss all details connected with the business
on which legislation might be required. Further,
this council received the reports of the searchers high
officers taken from their own body, whose business
was to inspect, in company with the lord mayor or
some other city dignitary, the shops of the respective
traders; to receive complaints, and to examine into
them. In each provincial town local councils
sate in connection with the municipal authorities,
who fulfilled in these places the same duties; and
their reports being forwarded to the central body,
and considered by them, representations on all necessary
matters were then made to the privy council; and by
the privy council, if requisite, were submitted to
parliament. If these representations were judged
to require legislative interference, the statutes
which were passed in consequence were returned through
the Chancellor to the mayors of the various towns and
cities, by whom they were proclaimed as law.
No person was allowed to open a trade or to commence
a manufacture, either in London or the provinces, unless
he had first served his apprenticeship; unless he
could prove to the satisfaction of the authorities
that he was competent in his craft; and unless he
submitted as a matter of course to their supervision.
The legislature had undertaken not to let that indispensable
task go wholly unattempted, of distributing the various
functions of society by the rule of capacity; of compelling
every man to do his duty in an honest following of
his proper calling, securing to him that he in his
turn should not be injured by his neighbour’s
misdoings.
The state further promising for itself
that all able-bodied men should be found in work,
and not allowing any man to work at a business for
which he was unfit, insisted as its natural right
that children should not be allowed to grow up in
idleness, to be returned at mature age upon its hands.
Every child, so far as possible, was to be trained
up in some business or calling, idleness “being
the mother of all sin,” and the essential duty
of every man being to provide honestly for himself
and his family. The educative theory, for such
it was, was simple but effective: it was based
on the single principle that, next to the knowledge
of a man’s duty to God, and as a means towards
doing that duty, the first condition of a worthy life
was the ability to maintain it in independence.
Varieties of inapplicable knowledge might be good,
but they were not essential; such knowledge might
be left to the leisure of after years, or it might
be dispensed with without vital injury. Ability
to labour could not be dispensed with, and this, therefore,
the state felt it to be its own duty to see provided;
so reaching, I cannot but think, the heart of the whole
matter. The children of those who could afford
the small entrance fees were apprenticed to trades,
the rest were apprenticed to agriculture; and if children
were found growing up idle, and their fathers or their
friends failed to prove that they were able to secure
them an ultimate maintenance, the mayors in towns
and the magistrates in the country had authority to
take possession of such children, and apprentice them
as they saw fit, that when they grew up “they
might not be driven” by want or incapacity “to
dishonest courses."
Such is an outline of the organisation
of English society under the Plantagenets and Tudors.
A detail of the working of the trade laws would be
beyond my present purpose. It is obvious that
such laws could be enforced only under circumstances
when production and population remained (as I said
before) nearly stationary; and it would be madness
to attempt to apply them to the changed condition
of the present. It would be well if some competent
person would make these laws the subject of a special
treatise. I will run the risk, however, of wearying
the reader with two or three illustrative statutes,
which I have chosen, not as being more significant
than many others, but as specimens merely of the discipline
under which, for centuries, the trade and manufactures
of England contrived to move; showing on one side
the good which the system effected, on the other the
inevitable evils under which it finally sank.
The first which I shall quote concerns
simply the sale of specific goods and the means by
which tradesmen were prevented from enhancing prices.
The Act is the 6th of the 24th of Henry VIII., and
concerns the sale of wines, the statute prices of
which I have already mentioned.
“Because,” says this Act,
“that divers merchants inhabiting within the
city of London have of late not only presumed to bargain
and sell in gross to divers of the king’s subjects
great quantities of wines of Gascony, Guienne, and
French wines, some for five pounds per tonne, some
for more and some for less, and so after the rate
of excessive prices contrary to the effect of a good
and laudable statute lately made in this present parliament;
that is to say, contrary to and above the prices thereof
set by the Right Honourable Lord Chancellor, Lord
Treasurer, Lord President of the King’s most
honourable Council, Lord Privy Seal, and the two Chief
Justices of either bench, whereby they be fallen into
the penalties limited by the said statute; as by due
proof made by examination taken is well known but
also having in their hands great abundance of wine,
by them acquired and bought to be sold, obstinately
and maliciously, since their said attemptate and defaults
proved, have refused to bargain and sell to many of
the king’s subjects any of their said wines
remaining and being in their hands; purposing and
intending thereby their own singular and unreasonable
lucres and profits, to have larger and higher
prices of their said wines, to be set according to
their insatiable appetites and minds; it is therefore
ordained and enacted, by authority of this present
parliament, that every merchant now having, or which
shall hereafter have, wines to be sold, and refusing
to sell or deliver, or not selling and delivering any
of the said wines for ready money therefore to be
paid, according to the price or prices thereof being
set, shall forfeit and lose the value of the wine so
required to be bought.... For due execution of
which provision, and for the relief of the king’s
subjects, it shall be lawful to all and singular justices
of the peace, mayors, bailiffs, and other head officers
in shires, cities, boroughs, towns, etc., at
the request of any person to whom the said merchant
or merchants have refused to sell, to enter into the
cellars and other places where such wines shall lie
or be, and to sell and deliver the same wine or wines
desired to be bought to the person or persons requiring
to buy the same; taking of the buyer of the wine so
sold to the use and satisfaction of the proprietor
aforesaid, according to the prices determined by the
law.”
The next which I select is the eleventh
of the second and third of Philip and Mary; and falling
in the midst of the smoke of the Smithfield fires,
and the cruelties of that melancholy time, it shines
like a fair gleam of humanity, which will not lose
anything of its lustre because the evils against which
it contends have in our times, also, furnished matter
for sorrow and calamity calamity which
we unhappily have been unable even to attempt to remedy.
It is termed “An Act touching Weavers,”
and runs:
“Forasmuch as the weavers of
this realm have, as well at this present parliament
as at divers other times, complained that the rich
and wealthy clothiers do in many ways oppress them some
by setting up and keeping in their houses divers looms,
and keeping and maintaining them by journeymen and
persons unskilful, to the decay of a great number of
artificers which were brought up in the said science
of weaving, with their families and their households some
by engrossing of looms into their hands and possession,
and letting them out at such unreasonable rents, as
the poor artificers are not able to maintain themselves,
much less maintain their wives, families, and children some
also by giving much less wages and hire for weaving
and workmanship than in times past they did, whereby
they are enforced utterly to forsake their art and
occupation wherein they have been brought up; It is,
therefore, for remedy of the premises, and for the
avoiding of a great number of inconveniences which
may grow if in time it be not foreseen, ordained and
enacted by authority of this present parliament, that
no person using the feat or mystery of cloth-making,
and dwelling out of a city, borough, market-town,
or corporate town, shall keep, or retain, or have
in his or their houses or possession, any more than
one woollen loom at a time; nor shall by any means,
directly or indirectly, receive or take any manner
of profit, gain, or commodity, by letting or setting
any loom, or any house wherein any loom is or shall
be used or occupied, which shall be together by him
set or let, upon pain of forfeiture for every week
that any person shall do the contrary to the tenor
and true meaning hereof, twenty shillings.”
A provision then follows, limiting
weavers living in towns to two looms the
plain intention being to prevent the cloth manufacture
from falling into the power of large capitalists employing
“hands;” and to enable as many persons
as possible to earn all in their own homes their own
separate independent living. I suppose that the
parliament was aware that by pursuing this policy
the cost of production was something increased; that
cloth was thus made dearer than it would have been
if trade had been left to follow its own course.
It considered, however, that the loss was compensated
to the nation by retaining its people in the condition
not of “hands,” but of men; by rendering
them independent of masters, who only sought to make
their own advantage at the expense of labour; and enabling
them to continue to maintain themselves in manly freedom.
The weak point of all such provisions did not lie,
I think, in the economic aspect of them, but in a
far deeper difficulty. The details of trade legislation,
it is obvious, could only be determined by persons
professionally conversant with those details; and
the indispensable condition of success with such legislation
is, that it be conducted under the highest sense of
the obligations of honesty. No laws are of any
service which are above the working level of public
morality; and the deeper they are carried down into
life, the larger become the opportunities of evasion.
That the system succeeded for centuries is evident
from the organisation of the companies remaining so
long in its vitality; but the efficiency of this organisation
for the maintenance of fair dealing could exist only
so long as the companies themselves their
wardens and their other officials, who alone, quisque
in sua arte, were competent to judge what was right
and what was wrong could be trusted, at
the same time being interested parties, to give a
disinterested judgment. The largeness of the power
inevitably committed to the councils was at once a
temptation and an opportunity to abuse those powers;
and slowly through the statute book we find the traces
of the poison as it crept in and in. Already
in the 24th of Henry VIII., we meet with complaints
in the leather trade of the fraudulent conduct of the
searchers, whose duty was to affix their seal upon
leather ascertained to be sound, before it was exposed
for sale, “which mark or print, for corruption
and lucre, is commonly set and put by such as take
upon them the search and sealing, as well upon leather
insufficiently tanned, as upon leather well tanned,
to the great deceit of the buyers thereof.”
About the same time, the “craft wardens”
of the various fellowships, “out of sinister
mind and purpose,” were levying excessive fees
on the admission of apprentices; and when parliament
interfered to bring them to order, they “compassed
and practised by cautill and subtle means to delude
the good and wholesome statutes passed for remedy."
The old proverb, Quis custodiat custodes, had
begun to verify itself, and the symptom was a fatal
one. These evils, for the first half of the century,
remained within compass; but as we pass on we find
them increasing steadily. In the 7th and the 8th
of Elizabeth, there are indications of the truck system;
and towards her later years, the multiplying statutes
and growing complaints and difficulties show plainly
that the companies had lost their healthy vitality,
and, with other relics of feudalism, were fast taking
themselves away. There were no longer tradesmen
to be found in sufficient numbers who were possessed
of the necessary probity; and it is impossible not
to connect such a phenomenon with the deep melancholy
which in those years settled down on Elizabeth herself.
For, indeed, a change was coming upon
the world, the meaning and direction of which even
still is hidden from us, a change from era to era.
The paths trodden by the footsteps of ages were broken
up; old things were passing away, and the faith and
the life of ten centuries were dissolving like a dream.
Chivalry was dying; the abbey and the castle were soon
together to crumble into ruins; and all the forms,
desires, beliefs, convictions of the old world were
passing away, never to return. A new continent
had risen up beyond the western sea. The floor
of heaven, inlaid with stars, had sunk back into an
infinite abyss of immeasurable space; and the firm
earth itself, unfixed from its foundations, was seen
to be but a small atom in the awful vastness of the
universe. In the fabric of habit in which they
had so laboriously built for themselves, mankind were
to remain no longer.
And now it is all gone like
an unsubstantial pageant faded; and between us and
the old English there lies a gulf of mystery which
the prose of the historian will never adequately bridge.
They cannot come to us, and our imagination can but
feebly penetrate to them. Only among the aisles
of the cathedral, only as we gaze upon their silent
figures sleeping on their tombs, some faint conceptions
float before us of what these men were when they were
alive; and perhaps in the sound of church bells, that
peculiar creation of mediaeval age, which falls upon
the ear like the echo of a vanished world.
The transition out of this old state
is what in this book I have undertaken to relate.
As yet there were uneasy workings below the surface;
but the crust was unbroken, and the nation remained
outwardly unchanged as it had been for centuries.
I have still some few features to add to my description.
Nothing, I think, proves more surely
the mutual confidence which held together the government
and the people, than the fact that all classes were
armed. Every man, as I have already said, was
a soldier; and every man was ready equipped at all
times with the arms which corresponded to his rank.
By the great statute of Winchester, which was repeated
and expanded on many occasions in the after reigns,
it was enacted, “That every man have harness
in his house to keep the peace after the antient assise that
is to say, every man between fifteen years of age
and sixty years shall be assessed and sworn to armour
according to the quantity of his lands and goods that
is, to wit, for fifteen pounds lands and forty marks
goods, a hauberke, a helmet of iron, a sword, a dagger,
and a horse. For ten pounds of lands and twenty
marks goods, a hauberke, a helmet, a sword, and a
dagger. For five pounds lands, a doublet, a helmet
of iron, a sword, and a dagger. For forty shillings
lands, a sword, a bow and arrows, and a dagger.
And all others that may shall have bows and arrows.
Review of armour shall be made every year two times,
by two constables for every hundred and franchise
thereunto appointed; and the constables shall present,
to justices assigned for that purpose, such defaults
as they do find.”
As the archery was more developed,
and the bow became the peculiar weapon of the English,
regular practice was ordered, and shooting became at
once the drill and the amusement of the people.
Every hamlet had its pair of butts; and on Sundays
and holidays all able-bodied men were required
to appear in the field, to employ their leisure hours
“as valyant Englishmen ought to do,” “utterly
leaving the play at the bowls, quoits, dice, kails,
and other unthrifty games;” magistrates, mayors,
and bailiffs being responsible for their obedience,
under penalty, if these officers neglected their duty,
of a fine of twenty shillings for each offence.
On the same days, the tilt-yard at the Hall or Castle
was thrown open, and the young men of rank amused
themselves with similar exercises. Fighting, or
mock fighting and the imitation was not
unlike the reality was at once the highest
enjoyment and the noblest accomplishment of all ranks
in the state; and over that most terrible of human
occupations they had flung the enchanted halo of chivalry,
decorating it with all the fairest graces, and consecrating
it with the most heroic aspirations.
The chivalry, with much else, was
often perhaps something ideal. In the wars of
the Roses it had turned into mere savage ferocity;
and in forty years of carnage the fighting propensities
had glutted themselves. A reaction followed,
and in the early years of Henry VIII. the statutes
were growing obsolete, and the “unlawful games”
rising again into favour. The younger nobles,
or some among them, were shrinking from the tilt-yard,
and were backward on occasions even when required
for war. Lord Surrey, when waiting on the Border,
expecting the Duke of Albany to invade the northern
counties, in 1523, complained of the growing “slowness”
of the young lords “to be at such journeys,"
and of their “inclination to dancing, carding,
and dicing.” The people had followed the
example, and were falling out of archery practice,
exchanging it for similar amusements. Henry VIII.,
in his earlier days an Englishman after the old type,
set himself resolutely to oppose these downward tendencies,
and to brace again the slackened sinews of the nation.
In his own person he was the best rider, the best
lance, and the best archer in England; and while a
boy he was dreaming of fresh Agincourts, and even
of fresh crusades. In 1511, when he had been
king only three years, parliament re-enacted the Winchester
statute, with new and remarkable provisions; and twice
subsequently in the course of his reign he returned
back upon the subject, insisting upon it with increasing
stringency. The language of the Act of 1511 is
not a little striking. “The King’s
Highness,” so the words run, “calling to
his gracious remembrance that by the feats and exercise
of the subjects of his realm in shooting in long bows,
there had continually grown and been within the same
great numbers and multitudes of good archers, which
hath not only defended the realm and the subjects
thereof against the cruel malice and dangers of their
enemies in times heretofore past, but also, with little
numbers and puissance in regard of their opposites,
have done many notable acts and discomfitures of war
against the infidels and others; and furthermore reduced
divers regions and countries to their due obeysance,
to the great honour, fame, and surety of this realm
and subjects, and to the terrible dread and fear of
all strange nations, anything to attempt or do to the
hurt or damage of them: Yet nevertheless that
archery and shooting in long bows is but little used,
but daily does minish and decay, and abate more and
more; for that much part of the commonalty and poor
people of this realm, whereby of old time the great
number and substance of archers had grown and multiplied,
be not of power nor ability to buy them long bows of
yew to exercise shooting in the same, and to sustain
the continual charge thereof; and also because, by
means and occasions of customable usage of tennis
play, bowles, claish and other unlawful games, prohibited
by many good and beneficent statutes, much impoverishment
hath ensued: Wherefore, the King’s Highness,
of his great wisdom and providence, and also for zeal
to the public weal, surety, and defence of this his
realm, and the antient fame in this behalf to be revived,
by the assent of his Lords Spiritual and Temporal,
and his Commons in this present parliament assembled,
hath enacted and established that the statute of Winchester
for archers be put in due execution; and over that,
that every man being the king’s subject, not
lame, decrepit, or maimed, being within the age of
sixty years, except spiritual men, justices of the
one bench and of the other, justices of the assize,
and barons of the exchequer, do use and exercise shooting
in long bows, and also do have a bow and arrows ready
continually in his house, to use himself in shooting.
And that every man having a man child or men children
in his house, shall provide for all such, being of
the age of seven years and above, and till they shall
come to the age of seventeen years, a bow and two
shafts, to learn them and bring them up in shooting;
and after such young men shall come to the age of seventeen
years, every of them shall provide and have a bow
and four arrows continually for himself, at his proper
costs and charges, or else of the gift and provision
of his friends, and shall use the same as afore is
rehearsed.” Other provisions are added,
designed to suppress the games complained of, and to
place the bows more within the reach of the poor,
by cheapening the prices of them.
The same statute (and if this
be a proof that it had imperfectly succeeded, it is
a proof also of Henry’s confidence in the general
attachment of his subjects) was re-enacted thirty years
later, at the crisis of the Reformation, when the
northern counties were fermenting in a half-suppressed
rebellion, and the catholics at home and abroad were
intriguing to bring about a revolution. In this
subsequent edition of it some particulars are
added which demand notice. In the directions to
the villages for the maintaining each “a pair
of buttes,” it is ordered that no person above
the age of twenty-four shall shoot with the light
flight arrow at a distance under two hundred and twenty
yards. Up to two hundred and twenty yards, therefore,
the heavy war arrow was used, and this is to be taken
as the effective range for fighting purposes of the
old archery. No measures could have been invented
more effective than this vigorous arming to repress
the self-seeking tendencies in the mercantile classes
which I have mentioned as beginning to show themselves.
Capital supported by force may make its own terms
with labour; but capital lying between a king on one
side resolved to prevent oppression, and a people on
the other side in full condition to resist, felt even
prudence dictate moderation, and reserved itself for
a more convenient season.
Looking, therefore, at the state of
England as a whole, I cannot doubt that under Henry
the body of the people were prosperous, well-fed, loyal,
and contented. In all points of material comfort
they were as well off as they had ever been before;
better off than they have ever been in later times.
Their amusements, as prescribed by
statute, consisted in training themselves as soldiers.
In the prohibitions of the statutes we see also what
their amusements were inclined to be. But besides
“the bowles and the claish,” field sports,
fishing, shooting, hunting, were the delight of every
one, and although the forest laws were terrible, they
served only to enhance the excitement by danger.
Then, as now, no English peasant could be convinced
that there was any moral crime in appropriating the
wild game. It was an offence against statute
law, but no offence against natural law; and it was
rather a trial of skill between the noble who sought
to monopolise a right which seemed to be common to
all, and those who would succeed, if they could, in
securing their own share of it. The Robin Hood
ballads reflect the popular feeling and breathe the
warm genial spirit of the old greenwood adventurers.
If deer-stealing was a sin, it was more than compensated
by the risk of the penalty to which those who failed
submitted, when no other choice was left. They
did not always submit, as the old northern poem shows
of Adam Bell, Clym of the Clough, and William of
Cloudislee, with its most immoral moral; yet I
suppose there was never pedant who could resist the
spell of those ringing lines, or refuse with all his
heart to wish the rogues success, and confusion to
the honest men.
But the English peasantry had pleasures
of less ambiguous propriety, and less likely to mislead
our sympathies. The chroniclers have given us
many accounts of the masques and plays which were
acted in the court, or in the castles of the noblemen.
Such pageants were but the most splendid expression
of a taste which was national and universal. As
in ancient Greece, generations before the rise of
the great dramas of Athens, itinerant companies wandered
from village to village, carrying their stage furniture
in their little carts, and acted in their booths and
tents the grand stories of the mythology; so in England
the mystery players haunted the wakes and fairs, and
in barns or taverns, taprooms, or in the farmhouse
kitchen, played at saints and angels, and transacted
on their petty stage the drama of the Christian faith.
To us, who can measure the effect of such scenes only
by the impression which they would now produce upon
ourselves, these exhibitions can seem but unspeakably
profane; they were not profane when tendered in simplicity,
and received as they were given. They were no
more profane than those quaint monastic illuminations
which formed the germ of Italian art; and as out of
the illuminations arose those paintings which remain
unapproached and unapproachable in their excellence,
so out of the mystery plays arose the English drama,
represented in its final completeness by the creations
of a poet who, it now begins to be supposed, stands
alone among mankind. We allow ourselves to think
of Shakspeare or of Raphael or of Phidias, as having
accomplished their work by the power of their own
individual genius; but greatness like theirs is never
more than the highest degree of an excellence which
prevails widely round it, and forms the environment
in which it grows. No single mind in single contact
with the facts of nature could have created out of
itself a Pallas, a Madonna, or a Lear; such vast conceptions
are the growth of ages, the creations of a nation’s
spirit; and artist and poet, filled full with the
power of that spirit, have but given them form, and
nothing more than form. Nor would the form itself
have been attainable by any isolated talent. No
genius can dispense with experience; the aberrations
of power, unguided or ill-guided, are ever in proportion
to its intensity, and life is not long enough to recover
from inevitable mistakes. Noble conceptions already
existing, and a noble school of execution which will
launch mind and hand at once upon their true courses,
are indispensable to transcendent excellence; and
Shakspeare’s plays were as much the offspring
of the long generations who had pioneered his road
for him, as the discoveries of Newton were the offspring
of those of Copernicus.
No great general ever arose out of
a nation of cowards; no great statesman or philosopher
out of a nation of fools; no great artist out of a
nation of materialists; no great dramatist except
when the drama was the passion of the people.
Acting was the especial amusement of the English, from
the palace to the village green. It was the result
and expression of their power over themselves, and
power over circumstances. They were troubled
with no subjective speculations; no social problems
vexed them with which they were unable to deal; and
in the exuberance of vigour and spirits they were
able, in the strict and literal sense of the word,
to play with the materials of life. The mystery
plays came first; next the popular legends; and then
the great figures of English history came out upon
the stage, or stories from Greek and Roman writers;
or sometimes it was an extemporised allegory.
Shakspeare himself has left us many pictures of the
village drama. Doubtless he had seen many a Bottom
in the old Warwickshire hamlets; many a Sir Nathaniel
playing “Alissander,” and finding himself
“a little o’erparted.” He had
been with Snug the joiner, Quince the carpenter, and
Flute the bellows-mender, when a boy we will not question,
and acted with them, and written their parts for them;
had gone up with them in the winter’s evenings
to the Lucy’s Hall before the sad trouble with
the deer-stealing; and afterwards, when he came to
London and found his way into great society, he had
not failed to see Polonius burlesquing Cæsar on the
stage, as in his proper person Polonius burlesqued
Sir William Cecil. The strolling players in Hamlet
might be met at every country wake or festival; it
was the direction in which the especial genius of the
people delighted to revel. As I desire in this
chapter not only to relate what were the habits of
the people, but to illustrate them also, within such
compass as I can allow myself, I shall transcribe out
of Hall a description of a play which was acted
by the boys of St. Paul’s School, in 1527, at
Greenwich, adding some particulars, not mentioned by
Hall, from another source. It is a good instance
of the fantastic splendour with which exhibitions
of this kind were got up, and it possesses also a
melancholy interest of another kind, as showing how
little the wisest among us can foresee our own actions,
or assure ourselves that the convictions of to-day
will alike be the convictions of to-morrow. The
occasion was the despatch of a French embassy to England,
when Europe was outraged by the Duke of Bourbon’s
capture of Rome, when the children of Francis I. were
prisoners in Spain, and Henry, with the full energy
of his fiery nature, was flinging himself into a quarrel
with Charles V. as the champion of the Holy See.
At the conclusion of a magnificent
supper “the king led the ambassadors into the
great chamber of disguisings; and in the end of the
same chamber was a fountain, and on one side was a
hawthorne tree, all of silk, with white flowers, and
on the other side was a mulberry tree full of fair
berries, all of silk. On the top of the hawthorne
were the arms of England, compassed with the collar
of the order of St. Michael, and in the top of
the mulberry tree stood the arms of France within a
garter. The fountain was all of white marble,
graven and chased; the bases of the same were balls
of gold, supported by ramping beasts wound in leaves
of gold. In the first work were gargoylles of
gold, fiercely faced with spouts running. The
second receit of this fountain was environed with winged
serpents, all of gold, which griped it; and on the
summit of the same was a fair lady, out of whose breasts
ran abundantly water of marvellous delicious savour.
About this fountain were benches of rosemary, fretted
in braydes laid on gold, all the sides set with roses,
on branches as they were growing about this fountain.
On the benches sate eight fair ladies in strange attire,
and so richly apparelled in cloth of gold, embroidered
and cut over silver, that I cannot express the cunning
workmanship thereof. Then when the king and queen
were set, there was played before them, by children,
in the Latin tongue, a manner of tragedy, the effect
whereof was that the pope was in captivity and the
church brought under foot. Whereupon St. Peter
appeared and put the cardinal (Wolsey) in authority
to bring the pope to his liberty, and to set up the
church again. And so the cardinal made intercession
with the kings of England and France that they took
part together, and by their means the pope was delivered.
Then in came the French king’s children, and
complained to the cardinal how the emperour kept them
as hostages, and would not come to reasonable point
with their father, whereupon they desired the cardinal
to help for their deliverance; which wrought so with
the king his master and the French king that he brought
the emperour to a peace, and caused the two young princes
to be delivered.” So far Hall relates the
scene, but there was more in the play than he remembered
or cared to notice, and I am able to complete this
curious picture of a pageant once really and truly
a living spectacle in the old palace at Greenwich,
by an inventory of the dresses worn by the boys and
a list of the dramatis personae.
The school-boys of St. Paul’s
were taken down the river with the master in six boats,
at the cost of a shilling a boat the cost
of the dresses and the other expenses amounting in
all to sixty-one shillings.
The characters were
An orator in apparel of cloth of gold.
Religio, Ecclesia, Veritas,
like three widows, in garments of silk, and suits
of lawn and Cyprus.
Heresy and False Interpretation, like
sisters of Bohemia, apparelled in silk of divers colours.
The heretic Luther, like a party friar,
in russet damask and black taffety.
Luther’s wife, like a frow of
Spiers in Almayn, in red silk.
Peter, Paul, and James, in habits
of white sarsnet, and three red mantles, and lace
of silver and damask, and pelisses of scarlet.
A Cardinal in his apparel.
Two Sergeants in rich apparel.
The Dolphin and his brother in coats
of velvet embroidered with gold, and capes of satin
bound with velvet.
A Messenger in tinsel satin.
Six men in gowns of grey sarsnet.
Six women in gowns of crimson velvet.
War, in rich cloth of gold and feathers, armed.
Three Almeyns, in apparel all cut and holed in silk.
Lady Peace in lady’s apparel white and rich.
Lady Quietness and Dame Tranquillity richly beseen
in lady’s apparel.
It is a strange world. This was
in November, 1527. In November, 1530, but three
brief years after, Wolsey lay dying in misery, a disgraced
man, at Leicester Abbey; “the Pope’s Holiness”
was fast becoming in English eyes plain Bishop of
Rome, held guilty towards this realm of unnumbered
enormities, and all England was sweeping with immeasurable
velocity towards the heretic Luther. So history
repeats the lesson to us, not to boast ourselves of
the morrow, for we know not what a day may bring forth.
Before I conclude this survey, it
remains for me to say something of the position of
the poor, and of the measures which were taken for
the solution of that most difficult of all problems,
the distinguishing the truly deserving from the worthless
and the vagabond. The subject is one to which
in the progress of this work I shall have more than
one occasion to return; but inasmuch as a sentimental
opinion prevails that an increase of poverty and the
consequent enactment of poor-laws was the result of
the suppression of the religious houses, and that
adequate relief had been previously furnished by these
establishments, it is necessary to say a few words
for the removal of an impression which is as near
as possible the reverse of the truth. I do not
doubt that for many centuries these houses fulfilled
honestly the intentions with which they were established;
but as early as the reign of Richard II. it was found
necessary to provide some other means for the support
of the aged and impotent; the monasteries not only
having then begun to neglect their duty; but by the
appropriation of bénéfices having actually deprived
the parishes of their local and independent means
of charity. Licences to beg were at that time granted
to deserving persons; and it is noticeable that this
measure was in a few years followed by the petition
to Henry IV. for the secularisation of ecclesiastical
property. Thus early in our history had the regular
clergy forgotten the nature of their mission, and
the object for which the administration of the nation’s
charities had been committed to them. Thus early,
while their houses were the nurseries of dishonest
mendicancy, they had surrendered to lay compassion,
those who ought to have been their especial care.
I shall unhappily have occasion hereafter to illustrate
these matters in detail. I mention them in this
place only in order to dissipate at once a foolish
dream. At the opening of the sixteenth century,
before the suppression of the monasteries had suggested
itself in a practical form, pauperism was a state
question of great difficulty, and as such I have at
present to consider it.
For the able-bodied vagrant, it is
well known that the old English laws had no mercy.
When wages are low, and population has outgrown the
work which can be provided for it, idleness may be
involuntary and innocent; at a time when all industrious
men could maintain themselves in comfort and prosperity,
“when a fair day’s wages for a fair day’s
work” was really and truly the law of the land,
it was presumed that if strong capable men preferred
to wander about the country, and live upon the labour
of others, mendicancy was not the only crime of which
they were likely to be guilty; while idleness itself
was justly looked upon as a high offence, and misdemeanour.
The penalty of God’s laws against idleness, as
expressed in the system of nature, was starvation;
and it was held intolerable that any man should be
allowed to escape a divine judgment by begging under
false pretences, and robbing others of their honest
earnings.
In a country also the boast of which
was its open-handed hospitality, it was necessary
to take care that hospitality was not brought to discredit
by abuse; and when every door was freely opened to
a request for a meal or a night’s lodging, there
was an imperative duty to keep a strict eye on whatever
persons were on the move. We shall therefore be
prepared to find “sturdy and valiant beggars”
treated with summary justice as criminals of a high
order; the right of a government so to treat them being
proportioned to the facilities with which the honestly
disposed can maintain themselves.
It might have been expected, on the
other hand, that when wages were so high, and work
so constant, labourers would have been left to themselves
to make provision against sickness and old age.
To modern ways of thinking on these subjects, there
would have seemed no hardship in so leaving them; and
their sufferings, if they had suffered, would have
appeared but as a deserved retribution. This,
however, was not the temper of earlier times.
Charity has ever been the especial virtue of Catholic
States, and the aged and the impotent were always
held to be the legitimate objects of it. Men
who had worked hard while they were able to work were
treated like decayed soldiers, as the discharged pensionaries
of society; they were held entitled to wear out their
age (under restrictions) at the expense of others;
and so readily did society acquiesce in this aspect
of its obligations, that on the failure of the monasteries
to do their duty, it was still sufficient to leave
such persons to voluntary liberality, and legislation
had to interfere only to direct such liberality into
its legitimate channels. In the 23rd of Edw.
III. ca, a prohibition was issued against giving
alms to “valiant beggars,” and this proving
inadequate, and charity being still given indiscriminately,
in the twelfth year of Richard II. the system of licences
was introduced, and a pair of stocks was erected by
order in every town or village, to “justify”
persons begging unpermitted. The monasteries
growing more and more careless, the number of paupers
continued to multiply, and this method received successive
expansions, till at length, when the Reformation was
concluded, it terminated, after many changes of form,
in the famous Act of Elizabeth. We can thus trace
our poor law in the whole course of its growth, and
into two stages through which it passed I must enter
with some minuteness. The 12th of the 22nd of
Henry VIII., and the 25th of the 27th, are so remarkable
in their tone, and so rich in their detail, as to furnish
a complete exposition of English thought at that time
upon the subject; while the second of these two acts,
and probably the first also, has a further interest
for us, as being the composition of Henry himself,
and the most finished which he has left to us.
“Whereas,” says the former
of these two Acts, “in all places throughout
this realm of England, vagabonds and beggars have of
long time increased, and daily do increase in great
and excessive numbers, by the occasion of idleness,
mother and root of all vices; whereby hath insurged
and sprung, and daily insurgeth and springeth, continual
thefts, murders, and other heinous offences and great
enormities, to the high displeasure of God, the inquietation
and damage of the king’s people, and to the marvellous
disturbance of the common weal of this realm; and whereas,
strait statutes and ordinances have been before this
time devised and made, as well by the king our sovereign
lord, as also by divers his most noble progenitors,
kings of England, for the most necessary and due reformation
of the premises; yet that notwithstanding, the said
number of vagabonds and beggars be not seen in any
part to be diminished, but rather daily augmented
and increased into great routs or companies, as evidently
and manifestly it doth and may appear: Be it
therefore enacted by the king our sovereign lord,
and by the Lords Spiritual and Temporal, and the Commons,
in this present parliament assembled, that the justices
of the peace of all and singular the shires of England
within the limits of their commission, and all other
justices of the peace, mayors, sheriffs, bailiffs,
and other officers of every city, borough, or franchise,
shall from time to time, as often as need shall require,
make diligent search and inquiry of all aged, poor,
and impotent persons, which live, or of necessity be
compelled to live by alms of the charity of the people;
and such search made, the said officers, every of
them within the limits of their authorities, shall
have power, at their discretions, to enable to beg
within such limits as they shall appoint, such of
the said impotent persons as they shall think convenient;
and to give in commandment to every such impotent beggar
(by them enabled) that none of them shall beg without
the limits so appointed to them. And further,
they shall deliver to every such person so enabled
a letter containing the name of that person, witnessing
that he is authorised to beg, and the limits within
which he is appointed to beg, the same letter to be
sealed with the seal of the hundred, rape, wapentake,
city, or borough, and subscribed with the name of
one of the said justices or officers aforesaid.
And if any such impotent person do beg in any other
place than within such limits, then the justices of
the peace, and all other the king’s officers
and ministers, shall by their discretions punish all
such persons by imprisonment in the stocks, by the
space of two days and two nights, giving them only
bread and water.”
Further, “If any such impotent
person be found begging without a licence, at the
discretion of the justices of the peace, he shall be
stripped naked from the middle upwards, and whipped
within the town in which he be found, or within some
other town, as it shall seem good. Or if it be
not convenient so to punish him, he shall be set in
the stocks by the space of three days and three nights.”
Such were the restrictions under which
impotency was allowed support. Though not in
itself treated as an offence, and though its right
to maintenance by society was not denied, it was not
indulged, as we may see, with unnecessary encouragement.
The Act then proceeds to deal with the genuine vagrant.
“And be it further enacted,
that if any person or persons, being whole and mighty
in body and able to labour, be taken in begging in
any part of this realm; and if any man or woman, being
whole and mighty in body, having no land, nor master,
nor using any lawful merchandry, craft, or mystery
whereby he might get his living, be vagrant, and can
give none account how he doth lawfully get his living,
then it shall, be lawful to the constables and all
other king’s officers, ministers, and subjects
of every town, parish, and hamlet, to arrest the said
vagabonds and idle persons, and bring them to any
justice of the peace of the same shire or liberty,
or else to the high constable of the hundred; and
the justice of the peace, high constable, or other
officer, shall cause such idle person so to him brought,
to be had to the next market town or other place, and
there to be tied to the end of a cart, naked, and
be beaten with whips throughout the same town till
his body be bloody by reason of such whipping; and
after such punishment of whipping had, the person
so punished shall be enjoined upon his oath to return
forthwith without delay, in the next and straight
way, to the place where he was born, or where he last
dwelled before the same punishment, by the space of
three years; and then put himself to labour like a
true man ought to do; and after that done, every such
person so punished and ordered shall have a letter,
sealed with the seal of the hundred, rape, or wapentake,
witnessing that he hath been punished according to
this estatute, and containing the day and place of
his punishment, and the place where unto he is limited
to go, and by what time he is limited to come thither:
for that within that time, showing the said letter,
he may lawfully beg by the way, and otherwise not;
and if he do not accomplish the order to him appointed
by the said letter, then to be eftsoons taken and
whipped; and so often as there be fault found in him,
to be whipped till he has his body put to labour for
his living, or otherwise truly get his living, so
long as he is able to do so.”
Then follow the penalties against
the justices of the peace, constables, and all officers
who neglect to arrest such persons; and a singularly
curious catalogue is added of certain forms of “sturdy
mendicancy,” which, if unspecified, might have
been passed over as exempt, but to which Henry had
no intention of conceding further licence. It
seems as if, in framing the Act, he had Simon Fish’s
petition before him, and was commencing at last the
rough remedy of the cart’s-tail, which Fish had
dared to recommend for a very obdurate evil. The
friars of the mendicant orders were tolerated for
a few years longer; but many other spiritual persons
may have suffered seriously under the provisions of
the present statute.
“Be it further enacted,”
the Act continues, “that scholars of the Universities
of Oxford and Cambridge, that go about begging, not
being authorised under the seal of the said universities,
by the commissary, chancellor, or vice-chancellor
of the same; and that all and singular shipmen pretending
losses of their ships and goods, going about the country
begging without sufficient authority, shall be punished
and ordered in manner and form as is above rehearsed
of strong beggars; and that all proctors and pardoners,
and all other idle persons going about in counties
or abiding in any town, city, or borough, some of them
using divers subtle, crafty, and unlawful games and
plays, and some of them feigning themselves to have
knowledge in physick, physnamye, and palmistry, or
other crafty science, whereby they bear the people
in hand that they can tell their destinies, dreams,
and fortunes, and such other like fantastical imaginations,
to the great deceit of the king’s subjects, shall,
upon examination had before two justices of the peace,
if by provable witness they be found guilty of such
deceits, be punished by whipping at two days together,
after the manner before rehearsed. And if they
eftsoons offend in the same or any like offence, to
be scourged two days, and the third day to be put
upon the pillory, from nine o’clock till eleven
the forenoon of the same day, and to have the right
ear cut off; and if they offend the third time, to
have like punishment with whipping and the pillory,
and to have the other ear cut off.”
It would scarcely have been expected
that this Act would have failed for want of severity
in its penalties; yet five years later, for this and
for some other reasons, it was thought desirable to
expand the provisions of it, enhancing the penalties
at the same time to a degree which has given a bloody
name in the history of English law to the statutes
of Henry VIII. Of this expanded statute we
have positive evidence, as I said, that Henry was
himself the author. The merit of it, or the guilt
of it if guilt there be originated
with him alone. The early clauses contain practical
amendments of an undoubtedly salutary kind. The
Act of 1531 had been defective in that no specified
means had been assigned for finding vagrants in labour,
which, with men of broken character, was not immediately
easy. The smaller monasteries having been suppressed
in the interval, and sufficient funds being thus placed
at the disposal of the government, public works
were set on foot throughout the kingdom, and this
difficulty was obviated.
Another important alteration was a
restriction upon private charity. Private persons
were forbidden, under heavy penalties, to give money
to beggars, whether deserving or undeserving.
The poor of each parish might call at houses within
the boundaries for broken meats; but this was the
limit of personal almsgiving; and the money which men
might be disposed to offer was to be collected by
the churchwardens on Sundays and holidays in the churches.
The parish priest was to keep an account of receipts
and of expenditure, and relief was administered with
some approach to modern formalities. A further
excellent but severe enactment empowered the parish
officers to take up all idle children above the age
of five years, “and appoint them to masters
of husbandry or other craft or labour to be taught;”
and if any child should refuse the service to which
he was appointed, or run away “without cause
reasonable being shown for it,” he might be
publicly whipped with rods, at the discretion of the
justice of the peace before whom he was brought.
So far, no complaint can be urged
against these provisions: they display only that
severe but true humanity, which, in offering fair and
liberal maintenance for all who will consent to be
honest, insists, not unjustly, that its offer shall
be accepted, and that the resources of charity shall
not be trifled away. On the clause, however, which
gave to the Act its especial and distinguishing character,
there will be large difference of opinion. “The
sturdy vagabond,” who by the earlier statute
was condemned on his second offence to lose the whole
or a part of his right ear, was condemned by the amended
Act, if found a third time offending, with the mark
upon him of his mutilation, “to suffer pains
and execution of death, as a felon and as an enemy
of the commonwealth.” So the letter stands.
For an able-bodied man to be caught a third time begging
was held a crime deserving death, and the sentence
was intended, on fit occasions, to be executed.
The poor man’s advantages, which I have estimated
at so high a rate, were not purchased without drawbacks.
He might not change his master at his will, or wander
from place to place. He might not keep his children
at his home unless he could answer for their time.
If out of employment, preferring to be idle, he might
be demanded for work by any master of the “craft”
to which he belonged, and compelled to work whether
he would or no. If caught begging once, being
neither aged nor infirm, he was whipped at the cart’s
tail. If caught a second time, his ear was slit,
or bored through with a hot iron. If caught a
third time, being thereby proved to be of no use upon
this earth, but to live upon it only to his own hurt
and to that of others, he suffered death as a felon.
So the law of England remained for sixty years.
First drawn by Henry, it continued unrepealed through
the reigns of Edward and of Mary, subsisting, therefore,
with the deliberate approval of both the great parties
between whom the country was divided. Reconsidered
under Elizabeth, the same law was again formally passed;
and it was, therefore, the expressed conviction of
the English nation, that it was better for a man not
to live at all than to live a profitless and worthless
life. The vagabond was a sore spot upon the commonwealth,
to be healed by wholesome discipline if the gangrene
was not incurable; to be cut away with the knife if
the milder treatment of the cart-whip failed to be
of profit.
A measure so extreme in its severity
was partly dictated by policy. The state of the
country was critical; and the danger from questionable
persons traversing it unexamined and uncontrolled
was greater than at ordinary times. But in point
of justice, as well as of prudence, it harmonised with
the iron temper of the age, and it answered well for
the government of a fierce and powerful people, in
whose hearts lay an intense hatred of rascality, and
among whom no one need have lapsed into evil courses
except by deliberate preference for them. The
moral substance of the English must have been strong
indeed when it admitted of such hardy treatment; but
on the whole, the people were ruled as they preferred
to be ruled; and if wisdom may be tested by success,
the manner in which they passed the great crisis of
the Reformation is the best justification of their
princes.
The era was great throughout Europe.
The Italians of the age of Michael Angelo; the Spaniards
who were the contemporaries of Cortez; the Germans
who shook off the pope at the call of Luther; and the
splendid chivalry of Francis I. of France, were no
common men. But they were all brought face to
face with the same trials, and none met them as the
English met them. The English alone never lost
their self-possession; and if they owed something
to fortune in their escape from anarchy, they owed
more to the strong hand and steady purpose of their
rulers.
To conclude this chapter then.
In the brief review of the system
under which England was governed, we have seen a state
of things in which the principles of political economy
were, consciously or unconsciously, contradicted;
where an attempt, more or less successful, was made
to bring the production and distribution of wealth
under the moral rule of right and wrong; and where
those laws of supply and demand, which we are now
taught to regard as immutable ordinances of nature,
were absorbed or superseded by a higher code.
It is necessary for me to repeat that I am not holding
up the sixteenth century as a model which the nineteenth
might safely follow. The population has become
too large, employment has become too complicated and
fluctuating, to admit of external control; while,
in default of control, the relapse upon self-interest
as the one motive principle is certain to ensue, and
when it ensues is absolute in its operations.
But as, even with us, these so-called ordinances of
nature in time of war consent to be suspended, and
duty to his country becomes with every good citizen
a higher motive of action than the advantages which
he may gain in an enemy’s market; so it is not
uncheering to look back upon a time when the nation
was in a normal condition of militancy against social
injustice; when the government was enabled by happy
circumstances to pursue into detail a single and serious
aim at the well-being well-being in its
widest sense of all members of the commonwealth.
The world, indeed, was not made particularly pleasant.
Of liberty, in the modern sense of the word, of the
supposed right of every man “to do what he will
with his own” or with himself, there was no idea.
To the question, if ever it was asked, May I not do
what I will with my own? there was the brief answer,
No man may do what is wrong, either with that which
is his own or with that which is another’s.
Workmen were not allowed to take advantage of the
scantiness of the labour market to exact extravagant
wages. Capitalists were not allowed to drive the
labourers from their holdings, and destroy their healthy
independence. The antagonism of interests was
absorbed into a relation of which equity was something
more than the theoretic principle, and employers and
employed were alike amenable to a law which both were
compelled to obey. The working man of modern
times has bought the extension of his liberty at the
price of his material comfort. The higher classes
have gained in luxury what they have lost in power.
It is not for the historian to balance advantages.
His duty is with the facts.