VARIETIES OF ECONOMIC GOODS
Passive Capital Goods. - Labor
spends itself on materials, and these, in their rawest
state, are furnished by nature herself. They “ripen”
as the work goes on. Every touch that is put on
them imparts to them more of the utility which is
the essence of wealth. They are technically “goods,”
or concrete forms of wealth, from the moment when
they begin to acquire this utility, though for a time
they are in an unfinished state. The function
of materials, raw or partly finished, in the physical
operation of industry is a passive one, since they
receive utility and do not impart it. The iron
is passive under the blows of the blacksmith’s
hammer; leather is passive under the action of the
shoemaker’s sewing machine; a log is passive
under the action of the lumberman’s saw, etc.
The materials which are thus receiving utilities under
the producers’ manipulations constitute a distinct
variety of capital goods, while the implements which
help to impart the utilities constitute another variety,
and both kinds are present in all stages of industrial
evolution. Savages use raw materials and tools
for fashioning them.
Active Capital Goods. - The
hammer which fashions the iron, the awl which pierces
the leather, and the saw that cuts the log into boards
have an active function to perform. They do not
receive utilities, but impart them. They manipulate
other things and are not themselves manipulated; and
except as unavoidable wear and tear injure or destroy
them, they are not themselves at all changed by the
processes in which they take part. They are the
workman’s active assistants in the attacks that
he makes on the resisting elements of nature.
Passive instruments, then, and active ones - things
which receive utility, as industry goes on, and those
which impart utility - constitute the two
generic kinds of capital goods. What is commonly
called “circulating capital” is a permanent
stock of passive capital goods; and, in like manner,
what is usually known as “fixed capital”
is such a stock of capital goods of the active kind.
The materials and the unfinished goods that are scattered
through a modern mill and receiving utility are what
the manufacturer would at this moment identify if he
were asked to point out the things in which he has
circulating capital invested; while the mill, the
machinery, the land, etc., which are imparting
utility, are what he can point to as now constituting
his fixed capital. At a later time there will
be other goods of both kinds in his possession, and
these will at that time embody the two kinds of capital.
While a primitive man would have little occasion to
use the term capital goods, he would possess
both varieties of the goods which the term denotes.
Varieties of Active Capital Goods. - Mere
hand tools act as armatures attached to the person
of the worker, and they enable him effectively to
attack resisting substances. The hammer fortifies
the blacksmith’s hand against the injuries it
would suffer if he delivered blows with his fist,
and it multiplies the efficiency of the blows.
Machines, however, substitute themselves for the person
of the worker and carry the tool through its movements.
A steam hammer, so called, is an engine that gets
power from a boiler and wields an armature, which is
the real hammer, much as a smith would do it, though
with far greater force and effect. Machines do
rapidly and accurately what a manual laborer would,
without them, have to do slowly and imperfectly, by
carrying the armature in his own hand and moving it
by his own muscular strength. Tools and machines
impart “form utility” to materials.
Vehicles which carry goods impart “place utility”
to them by putting them where they are more useful
than they would be elsewhere. Buildings protect
goods and workers alike, and enable the operation
of transforming them to go on successfully. They
also make it possible to store goods at a time when
they are not needed and take them out for use when
they are needed. In doing this, buildings help
to impart “time utility” to the merchandise
that is put into them by keeping them intact till
the time comes when they will be useful. Tools,
machines, reservoirs of water, canals, roadways, buildings,
and even land itself are active capital goods, and
are, for that reason, component elements of that part
of the permanent productive fund which is known as
fixed capital. They aid workers in their efforts
to bring materials into usable shapes, and this is
as true of the hole in the earth in which a savage
stores provisions as it is of a fireproof warehouse
in a modern city.
Materials which are at first Passive
and later pass into the Active State. - The
hammer itself has to be made out of raw material, and,
while it is in the making, the material that enters
into it is as passive as anything else. While
the ore is smelting and while the steel is forging,
the future hammer is in a preliminary stage of its
existence and is discharging a passive function.
When it is completely finished, its period of activity
begins, and from this time on it helps to manipulate
other things. The materials which enter into
consumers’ goods go through no such transition.
The leather remains passive till, in the form of a
pair of shoes, it clothes its user’s feet; and
at this point it ceases to be a capital good at all.
The steel of the hammer is first a passive good and
later an active one.
The Use of Capital Goods Universal. - There
is no doubt that capital goods are used in the most
primitive industry. Implements existed in times
too remote for tracing; and even if they had not been
used, raw material would have been indispensable.
People living in an economic stage so ultraprimitive
as to use no mediate goods whatever could sustain
life only by plucking wild fruit or gathering fish
or other food stuff by hand, and so long as they could
do this their industry might conceivably consist in
getting consumers’ goods by labor only.
The rudest pick, shovel, or ax and the simplest hunting
implement are early types of what, in “capitalistic
production,” is represented by mills with their
intricate machines, ships, railroads, and the like.
Primitive industry has capital but is not highly capitalistic,
since labor and a little capital in simple forms are
all that it requires. These primitive capital
goods are still essential.
Capital. - It might
seem that we have already described the nature of
capital, but we have not. We have described the
kinds of goods of which it consists. A sharp
distinction is to be drawn between two ways of treating
capital goods, and only one of these ways affords a
treatment of capital properly so called. To attain
that concept we must think of goods as in some way
constituting a stock which abides as long as the business
continues. And yet the things themselves separately
considered do not abide. Goods are perishable
things; no one lasts forever, and some last only a
very short time. Raw materials best serve their
purpose when they are quickly transformed into usable
goods and taken out of the category of productive instruments.
Tools may last longer, but they ultimately wear out
and have to be replaced.
How Capital Goods Originate and
Perish. - If you watch a particular mediate
good of the passive kind, say wood in a growing tree,
you see it beginning its career as an absolutely raw
material, and then under the hand of labor, aided
by tools, receiving utility till it takes its final
form in some article for a consumer’s use, say
a dining table. Little labor is applied to it
during the first stage of the process, that in which
the tree is guarded and allowed to grow to a size that
fits it for conversion into lumber; but the cutting,
carrying, sawing, and fashioning are done by labor
and tools, and under their manipulations the wood
“ripens” in the economic sense - that
is, it becomes quite fit for consumption. It
is ready to serve a consumer as a table, and, when
this service begins, the wood that up to this point
has been a passive capital good, constantly receiving
utilities, will cease to be a capital good at all
and begin slowly to wear out in the service of its
owner.
The Transition of Goods from one
State to Another. - The beginning of
its service in the purchaser’s dining room takes
the wood of the table out of the category of producers’
goods; but there is some raw material that is never
destined to emerge from that category and enter another.
Its last state of existence as a good will be that
in which it is embodied, not in an article for consumers’
use, but in an active tool. Our tree might have
furnished some of its wood for a wheelbarrow, and
if so, that part of it would have been a capital good
until it ceased to be an economic good at all.
If we watch it as it grows toward its economic maturity,
we see it sawed, planed, and otherwise fashioned under
the laborer’s hand, and maintaining during all
this time its passive attitude, just as does the wood
that is destined to constitute a table. When
the wheelbarrow is completed, it does not, like the
table, begin to minister directly to consumers’
wants, but begins actively to aid some laborer in a
further productive operation. It carries mortar
to the wall of an unfinished building and is thus
taken out of the list of passive goods - recipients
of utility - and is ranged with other active
tools which impart utility. The same thing is
true of the steel that is destined to compose the
head of a modern woodman’s ax or the stone that
is in process of fashioning into the rude hatchet
of some primitive savage. As raw or partly wrought
material it is a passive capital good; later it becomes
an instrument of the active sort.
The Ultimate Perishability of all
Kinds of Goods artificially Made. - In
the end both kinds of material will cease to be capital
goods. The raw stuff that goes into food, clothing,
furnishings, or the like will become consumers’
goods, while the raw material of tools will, in its
final form, the tools themselves, have one more lease
of life as capital goods. In the end, however,
as wheelbarrows, axes, hatchets, and the whole long
list of active implements are used up, they cease
to be capital goods because they cease to be economic
goods at all. They are as truly ordained to be
ultimately used up as are food and clothing, and this
is true of the most durable things that are artificially
made. Walls, roadways, bridges, and buildings
slowly deteriorate till the time comes when for productive
purposes their room is worth more than their company.
Why the Perishability of Capital
Goods does not put Capital out of Existence. - Perishability
is the most striking trait of capital goods.
Each particular one comes and goes, but there is always
a stock of them on hand; for when one is on the point
of going, another is ready to take its place and keep
up the succession. New tools replace old tools;
new materials replace those that are finished and
withdrawn, and so it comes about that a stock of such
things abides forever. Not one of the individual
instruments is permanent, for each one only does its
part in keeping up an endless procession. It is
the procession that is always there - a moving
series of individual goods, not one of which has more
than a transient economic career. Each one helps
to keep up the supply of permanent capital just as
each man, taking his turn in an endless succession
of laborers, serves during his brief life to keep
up the permanent force of laboring humanity.
Men come and go, but “labor” - a
mass of working humanity - abides; and so
capital goods come and go, but a stock of them abides,
kept up by perpetual replacement. We may trace
the career of any single instrument from a beginning
to an end; but we may, on the other hand, cease to
look at any instruments that we single out and identify
and look rather at the procession of them; and if
we do this, we look at a body which never wastes away,
though the things that compose it are, separately
considered, forever wasting.
There are many kinds of transient
things which, by the same process of renewal, constitute
permanent entities. Composing a human body at
this moment are certain tissues that can be separately
identified; and if we watch any one of them, we shall
see it going in a short time to destruction.
Yet the body lasts while life continues. Indeed,
the evidence of the life itself is the discarding
and replacing of the tissues. A living body is
a durable thing, though the particular tissues that
at any one time compose it are not so. In a like
way drops of water make a river, and this is a permanent
thing, however rapidly its composition changes.
The waterfall that drives the machinery of a mill
is permanent, though no particular particle of water
remains in it for more than a moment. Society
is permanent, though the men who compose it are short-lived.
In an exactly similar way a body of capital goods
is maintained as a perpetual instrumentality of production.
This is capital properly so called. It is,
as it were, a quasi-living body, perpetuated by the
constant replacement of the component parts, which
are destroyed as its normal activities go on.
The Difference between Capital
Goods and Capital Summarized. - The distinction
between capital goods, on the one hand, and capital,
on the other, is, then, like that between particular
tissues and a living body, or like that between particular
particles of water in the river and the river that
flows forever. We can single out and watch certain
drops of the water as they flow from a spring, and
we can trace them through their brief careers, and
say truly that the river is composed of fickle and
transient stuff; but we cannot say that the river is
transient. That is perpetuated by the renewing
of the supply of water as the original drops disappear.
We can mentally watch a particular man, as he enters
the social force of workmen, labors for a time, and
drops out of the line, and can see that society is
composed of transient material; but society itself
is an abiding thing. So we can study a particular
bit of ore or wool or leather or a particular hammer
or spindle or sewing machine, and in those cases we
shall be studying capital goods and finding how perishable
they are; but we shall also see that a stock of them
always abides as the capital of economic society.
We can cease to look at individual things and study
the permanent fund of productive wealth, which is made
up of goods like ore, wool, leather, hammers, spindles,
and sewing machines. The identity of the things
which make up this stock is forever changing.
The same list of things we shall never find in the
stock on any two dates, but a supply of similar things
forever abides. Capital is this permanent fund
of productive goods, the identity of whose component
elements is forever changing. Capital goods are
the shifting component parts of this permanent aggregate.
They are the particular instruments that, each during
its own brief economic lifetime, take their places
in the endless procession of things which in its entirety
is an abiding productive agent - the co-worker
of labor and its perpetual assistant in creating consumers’
wealth.
The Business Man’s View of
Capital. - It is as such an abiding entity
that a business man regards capital. He describes
it nearly always as a sum of money. Thus the
capital of a manufacturer is “a million dollars”
because a stock of instruments worth that amount is
kept intact in his possession. It is not allowed
to waste away, however much the constituent parts
of it may shift. The waste and renewal which
business entails leave the equivalent of the million
dollars always on hand, though never in the literal
shape of money. A stock of shifting goods always
worth a million dollars is, by a figure of speech,
described as a million dollars “invested in the
goods."
The Chief Attribute of Capital. - A
chief attribute of capital, properly so called, is
permanence. If a man’s productive fund does
not last, he is impoverished. The farmer keeps
on hand a more or less constant supply of the implements
he has to use. He takes a part of the proceeds
of the sale of his crops, puts it into the shape of
implements and materials, and in this way keeps an
amount of them on hand as the auxiliary capital of
agriculture. Particular goods are not constant,
but the sum of money or quantum of wealth “invested”
in the moving procession of them is so. At any
one instant the capital is composed of particular
instruments which can be sought out and identified,
but at no two instants are the goods the same.
The Reasons for describing Capital
as a Sum of Money. - This fact explains
the general practice of describing capital in terms
of money. The manufacturer just referred to will
speak of his capital as “a million dollars”
and consider that sum as a “permanent investment”
because he knows that while the goods that now represent
that value will soon pass from him, the “dollars” - that
is, the value which is equivalent to the dollars - will
abide. There is, moreover, no failure on his
part to discriminate between his capital and literal
money, for he knows in what his productive fund consists,
and is fully aware that only the minutest part of
it is in the shape of actual currency.
Instruments of production compose
the fund, but the dollars serve to describe it.
They indicate the amount and the abiding quality of
it, since they describe what he has invested or embodied
in the shifting things and can, by a fair sale, get
out of them.
Why Abstract Terms are used in
popularly describing Capital. - In certain
connections money is, in unintelligent thinking, confused
with real capital in ways that we should guard against.
In avoiding such errors we need to be even more careful
that we do not miss the truth that is at the basis
of the common mode of describing capital. A permanent
fund that is spoken of as a million dollars invested
in a business does not suggest to any one a literal
pile of a million silver or paper dollars or of a
hundred thousand gold eagles. It suggests what
is actually in the business, a procession of things
each of which comes into the man’s possession
and then leaves him, and helps him to keep the constant
stock of goods that at any time is a potential million
of dollars. A permanent body of any kind, if it
is made up of shifting tissues, is commonly described
by the use of an abstract term. A waterfall,
made as it is of rapidly changing drops of water,
is spoken of as a “water power,” since
the power is the abiding thing. An endless series
of living human beings is described as “humanity,”
since that remains through all personal changes.
An endless series of workingmen is described as “labor,”
and we study the “wages of labor,” the
“relations of labor to capital,” etc.,
because these are permanent relations. Men come
and go, but labor continues and is the source of a
permanent income. It is actually the fact that
in speaking of the “labor problem” or the
“relation of capital and labor” we usually
think of “labor in the abstract,” as we
might term it; but this is very far from implying
that we consider a series of generations of actual
workingmen as an abstraction. We may, using terms
in a like way, speak of the problem of interest as
concerning “capital in the abstract”;
but this is far from meaning that we consider an endless
series of material instruments of industry an abstraction.
We describe these real things by the use of an abstract
term, just as we describe a thousand other realities.
A “fund,” a “value,” a “permanent
quantum of wealth,” is capital; but with the
abstract notion the mind always merges the thought
of the concrete entity. It is the tools of industry
that, in their endless march, come into and go out
of the industrial field that we think of even when
we use the abstract term. This term, however,
saves us from the danger of thinking merely of particular
tools that we can identify and trace to their final
destruction when we form the concept of capital.
The Importance of discriminating
between the Concept of Capital Goods and that of Capital. - Very
great is the importance of keeping sharply distinct
the two concepts of productive wealth of which one
is described by the term capital goods and
the other by the term capital. In the
one case we think of a particular thing which we identify,
keep in mind, and watch as it goes through its transformations,
does its final work, and perishes. The brilliant
studies of Professor Boehm-Bawerk are based on the
idea that such a tracing of the biography of a particular
instrument is the true way to solve the problem of
interest. Yet the very term interest itself
suggests the existence of what we have defined as permanent
capital - an abiding fund or sum of wealth
that every year yields as an income a certain percentage
of itself. The “hundred dollars” yields
five dollars; that is, the fund yields a twentieth
of the amount which, amid all the changes of its constituent
parts, it continues to embody. It is true, indeed,
that a study of all capital goods which have
existed or will exist, with due attention to their
relations to each other, would reveal the fact that
they maintain such an endless procession as has been
here described, and it would thus bring before the
mind such a concept of capital as the business man
has and describes by the monetary form of expression.
By making a synthetic study of capital goods in general,
and not separate studies of particular goods as they
come and go, we can obtain a grand resultant of the
action of all of them, which is nothing less than permanent
capital doing its continuous work. Such a comprehensive
study of capital goods, if it is carried far enough,
becomes a study of the abiding entity, capital.
Allowing ourselves, however, to put the abiding entity
out of sight and merely to trace the origin, growth,
and productive action of separate instruments of production
would be disastrous. The undying body in which
the particular things are tissues absolutely needs
to come into view. The very mention of a problem
of interest - of the percentage of itself
that a fund of a given amount can annually earn - puts
before us at once the permanent entity, capital, and
the problems relating to it.
Labor as a Permanent Entity. - The
term labor is sometimes used to describe a
permanent aggregation of laborers no one of whom lives
and works through more than a brief period. Labor
is thus analogous to capital and laborers to capital
goods. A permanent working force is composed
of perishable beings as a permanent producing fund
is composed of perishable goods. Both are commonly
described by the use of abstract terms, but both are
in reality concrete things; and actually to reduce
either to a mere abstraction would be to put a material
entity out of existence. We instinctively speak
of a value - a given number of dollars - in
describing a man’s capital, but it is dollars
“invested in” productive instruments; and
we instinctively speak of labor when we mean an abiding
force of workingmen. Neither capital nor labor
is like an immaterial soul that can live apart from
its body. Each consists of a permanent body with
a shifting composition. A permanent sum, on the
one hand, a permanent amount of working energy, on
the other, are always present, but they are in goods
and men respectively. Each may well be described
by the use of an abstract term, and in practical life
it commonly is so; but it is a concrete reality.
Peculiarity of Land as a Capital
Good. - One reservation needs to be made
when we call capital goods perishable. If we include
land under this term, we must make it an exception
to the rule of destructibility. It is the only
thing that does not go out of existence in the using.
It is not a produced good at all and does not stand,
like other goods, in an intermediate position between
labor and the gratification that labor is intended
to produce. Work did not create it and using
will not end it. It will be called, in our study,
a capital good, for it is a form of wealth which produces
other wealth. It enters into the permanent productive
fund that society is using.
Differences between Land and Other
Capital Goods Important in Economic Dynamics. - It
is in a later part of the study which deals with economic
changes - the part which we shall call Economic
Dynamics - that the differences between land
and artificially made goods become prominent, and
these differences will receive due emphasis in their
proper place. In studying the law which would
govern economic society if no essential economic changes
were taking place, - in reducing society,
as it were, to a static state, - we find
that there is a certain set of characteristics which
land shares with those capital goods which are the
products of human industry. In static studies
it is best to group the productive instruments which
men make with the one unmade good which nature furnishes
and to recognize that together they embody the permanent
fund of productive wealth.
Mobility an Attribute of Capital. - Even
in a static society capital would be permanent, while
particular capital goods would be perishable.
In dynamic studies another quality of capital, as
distinguished from capital goods, comes into the foreground,
namely, mobility. It is the power to move without
loss from one industry to another. Goods cannot
be thus moved with any freedom. A loom cannot
be taken out of a woolen mill and made to do duty
in a carpenter’s shop, nor can a circular saw
be made available in weaving. When the loom wears
out and needs replacement, it is in the owner’s
power to procure either another loom or a circular
saw, and if he chooses the latter alternative, he
causes capital to move into the woodworking business.
A whaling ship would not be useful as a cotton mill;
but much capital that was once invested in the whale
fishery of New England has since found its way into
manufacturing. The transfer can often be made
without waste. If the earnings of an instrument
have sufficed to replace it with another that is like
it, they may suffice for producing an instrument that
is unlike it. Waste, if it occurs, results from
a failure of the original instrument to earn the fund
for replacement. Capital which thus abides but
passes from one employment to another is a body the
identity and the character of whose component parts
change. The transfer of capital from one industry
to another is a dynamic phenomenon which is later
to be considered. What is here important is the
fact that it is in the main accomplished without entailing
transfers of capital goods. An instrument wears
itself out in one industry, and instead of being succeeded
by a like instrument in the same industry, it is succeeded
by one of a different kind which is used in a different
branch of production. Goods have not moved from
one branch to another, but capital has done so.
How Capital itself may be Destroyed. - When
we speak of capital as permanent, we mean that using
does not destroy it as it destroys the tissues of
which it is composed. Fires, earthquakes, and
business disasters put parts of it out of existence
and affect the volume of the fund as a whole; but
production itself leaves it intact. It is this
very production which destroys capital goods and makes
it necessary to replace them.