NORMAL VALUE
Natural Supply. - We
have attained a law of market value, which determines
the price at which a given amount of any commodity
will sell, and have taken a quick glance at the influence
which fixes the amount that is offered and thus furnishes
a natural standard to which the market value tends
to conform. At any one moment the amount which
is supplied is an exact quantity, and if it all has
to be sold, it will bring a price which is fixed by
the final utility of that amount of the commodity.
If the quantity offered for sale should become greater
or less, the final utility and the price would change.
Final utility controls the immediate selling price,
and if that is above the cost of production, a margin
of gain is afforded which appeals to producers, sets
competition working, and brings the quantity made up
to the full amount which can be sold at cost.
The amount of the supply itself is therefore not a
matter of chance or caprice. It is natural that
a certain quantity of each article should be supplied,
and that the price should hover about the level which
the final utility of that quantity of the good fixes.
“Natural” or “normal” price
is, in this view, the market price of a natural quantity.
Cost as a Standard of Normal Price. - It
is commonly and correctly stated that the normal price
of anything is that which just covers the cost of
producing it. Cost in this case is the total amount
of money that the entrepreneur pays out in
order to bring the commodity into existence.
He buys raw materials and pays for all the labor and
capital that transform them into a new and saleable
shape. If he can make a net profit, he does so;
but competition tends to adjust the quantity produced
and the consequent price in such a way that he can
make no net profit. What he gets for the article
will then reimburse him for his total outlay, but
it will do no more. Since the quantity produced
is normal when it brings the market price to this level
of cost, it appears that the cost is the ultimate
standard in the case. The quantity supplied varies
till it causes the market price just to cover the
cost; and so long as the quantity supplied is thus
natural, other influences remaining the same, the
price is so. This states the cost of production
in terms of money paid by an entrepreneur and
the returns from the operation as money received by
him; but there is a more philosophical way of conceiving
the law of cost, and to this we shall soon recur.
Elements of Cost. - Whatever
the entrepreneur has to pay for in the production
of an article is of course an element in its monetary
cost to him. If he does not begin the making
of it by drawing his raw materials from what nature
freely furnishes, he must pay some one for the raw
material. He must also pay for the labor, and
this is equivalent to buying the fraction of the article
that is produced by labor; for the laborer, as we
have seen, is the producer of a certain fractional
share of the article and the natural owner of that
share, and when he agrees to let his labor for hire,
what he really does is to sell out his individual
interest in the forthcoming product of the industry
in which he is about to engage. When a workman
in a shoe factory agrees to work for two dollars and
a half a day, he really contracts to sell every day
for that amount a certain quantity of shoes.
The leather is one element which enters into the finished
shoes, and therefore the entire shoe is not really
made in the factory; but of the part which is there
made, namely, the utility that results from transforming
the leather into shoes, one part is made by labor
and another by capital. The entrepreneur
has to buy both of these if he is to acquire a valid
title to the product and have a right to sell it.
These costs are therefore “purchase money”
paid for undivided shares of goods.
Labor of Management. - It
usually happens that an entrepreneur, or employer
of labor and capital, performs some labor himself;
and we have already noted the reason for this in the
fact that the kind of labor that he performs is so
important that the fate of the business often depends
on it. He may manage the business so well as to
make it succeed or so ill as to make it fail.
He pays himself for this labor when he draws a salary
for his services. As an entrepreneur he
treats his own labor as he does that of any one else
and buys the fraction of the product of his business
that his own labor of management has created.
In this he illustrates the general law that all payments
of wages are payments of the purchase of a certain
quantity of product. Though the owner’s
own contribution to the product is not always mentioned
in terms in the accounting, that is what his salary
is paid for, though it is spoken of as a payment for
his “time,” or his labor.
The Capitalist as the Vender of
a Share in a Product. - Capital, as we
have seen, also contributes a definite share toward
the total amount of every product in the making of
which it cooeperates. Labor does not do all the
transforming of leather into shoes which is done in
the factory, since machines, fuel, etc., help;
and we shall later find that there is a way of determining
how much of the product the help so given creates.
It adds a certain amount to what labor can claim as
its own special product, and the man who owns the capital
becomes the lawful claimant for this additional share.
When he agrees to let his capital work for an employer,
he virtually sells to the employer the undivided share
of the product - shoes or what not - that
the capital really creates. The furnisher of productive
instruments, like the furnisher of labor, is a vender,
and the entrepreneur is a buyer.
Entrepreneur and Capitalist. - As
was stated in an earlier chapter, an actual employer
nearly always furnishes some of the capital that he
uses. If he did not do so, he would have difficulty
in borrowing more, since banks or other lenders do
not loan to empty-handed men. It is clear that
what the employer gets in return for such capital as
he may put into the business is in reality a payment
for a contribution which that particular part of the
capital makes to the product. Since each bit
of capital in an establishment contributes something
toward the creating of the product, the employer’s
own capital has the same right to the value of its
contributary share as has the capital of any one else.
What the employer-capitalist gets for capital the employer,
pure and simple, pays. As the furnisher of instruments
the man is a vender of the product of these instruments,
while as an entrepreneur proper he is the buyer.
He must purchase the product of his own capital just
as he purchased the product of his own labor.
In paying, therefore, wages for all labor, including
what he performs himself, interest on all capital,
including his own, and the price of raw materials,
he gets something which, if competition does a perfect
work, he has to sell for what he gives for it.
The shoes, when he sells them, tend, under active
competition, to yield only what has been paid for
them in the making and, in a perfectly static state,
would actually yield no net profit. All the entrepreneur’s
costs, therefore, resolve themselves into purchase
money paid, his receipts are money accruing from sales;
and under ideally free competition the two sums total
are equal.
The Entrepreneur’s Proper
Function not Labor of Management. - In
some theoretical discussions the management of a business
figures as the principal function of the entrepreneur,
and all or nearly all of the reward that comes to
him is represented as coming in the shape of a reward
for a responsible kind of labor that calls great abilities
into requisition. But it is very clear that,
whether he personally performs any labor or not, the
employer has a distinctly mercantile function to perform;
and this in itself is totally unlike the work of overseeing
the mill, the shop, or the salesroom. He acquires
a title to the whole product by paying for the contributions
which labor and producers of raw material separately
make toward it, and then parts with the product; and
if he gets any more than he has paid out, he makes
a profit. When industry is in what we have termed
a dynamic state, such a difference between the value
of the product and the cost of the elements that go
into it is continually appearing, and that, too, largely
in consequence of causes over which, as a mere manager,
the employer has no control. A profit so gained
cannot be wages of management. It is a purely
commercial gain, or a difference between what is paid
for something and what is received for it.
Mercantile Profit. - It
is best, therefore, to distinguish in some perfectly
clear way between that function of the entrepreneur,
which consists in buying and selling, and any work
that he may find it best to do in the way of superintending
the business. At the cost of using the term entrepreneur
in a stricter sense than the one customarily attached
to it, we will make this word describe the purely mercantile
functionary who pays for the elements of a product
and then sells the product. The reason for the
very division between gains from this source and gains
from management we shall soon appreciate, for we shall
see that competition tends to reduce one of these incomes
to nothing, but tends to perpetuate the other and
to make the amount of it conform to a positive standard.
The entrepreneur, as we shall use the term,
is neither the manager nor the capitalist, and when
we have occasion to speak of either of these functionaries,
we shall call him by his own distinctive name; though
we know perfectly well that, in actual business, it
is desirable and often quite essential that the same
one who acts as an entrepreneur should also
put into the business some labor as well as some capital.
A man who performs two unlike functions, buying and
selling, on the one hand, and managing the business,
on the other, serves in two capacities that are clearly
distinguished from each other; while if he furnishes
any of the capital, he adds to these a third capacity
entitling him to the value of the product of his capital.
As a manager he directly aids in producing goods,
and he gets pay for so doing from his other self, the
entrepreneur, who acquires the title to the
goods; as a capitalist he has another legitimate claim
upon himself as entrepreneur.
These Distinctions recognized in
Practical Accounting. - That this is
no bit of mere theoretical subtlety is proved by the
fact that the bookkeeping of nearly all establishments
distinguishes between these two incomes by actually
putting an appraisal on the work the employer does
and paying a salary for it. A man may be a large
owner of stock in a corporation and yet receive a
salary that is fixed by an estimate of what an equally
useful man could be hired for. If personal influence
secures more for him than this, the excess is taken
from the pockets of the stockholders, and the amount
of it is accounted for in a way that does not fall
within the scope of pure economic law.
How “Natural” Prices
exclude Entrepreneur’s Profits. - The
old and correct view is that the tendency of competition
is to make things sell for enough to cover all costs,
as we have defined them, and no more. Under a
different phraseology this is what Ricardo and others
have rightly claimed. They were unconsciously
explaining what would happen in a static state, for
if society were actually in this state, the goods
that come out of the factory would be worth just enough
to reimburse the owner for all the outlays that can
be called costs. If they sell for more than this,
there is to be had from the business an income that
costs nothing. It is a net profit above all claims
based on personal labor or on the aid furnished by
capital, and it furnishes an incentive for enlarging
the business, and labor and capital are therefore
drawn into it. Entrepreneurs bring them and
for a time make a profit by this means; but as their
presence increases the output of goods that are here
made, it brings down the price till there is no inducement
to move any more labor and capital in this direction.
The Significance of a Natural Adjustment
of Different Industries. - The “natural”
state of general industry is that in which each particular
branch of it is in the no-profit state. It is
as though laborers and capitalists in a shoe factory
took all the shoes that it turns out, sold them in
a market, paid for the raw material out of the proceeds,
and kept the remainder, dividing it between themselves
in proportions which corresponded with the amounts
they had severally contributed toward the making of
this product; and as though the laborers in cotton
mills and iron foundries received the goods there
made and dealt with them in a like manner. It
is as though in every branch of business the whole
product were turned over in kind to the furnishers
of labor and capital.
The Entrepreneur a Passive Functionary
under Static Conditions. - Purely passive
is the function of the entrepreneur under static
conditions. In so far as any effect on his income
is concerned he might as well reside in a foreign
land as in the one where his business is located,
provided always that the management were unaffected.
When the same man is both entrepreneur and manager,
the absence of the first of these functionaries would
mean the absence also of the second, and that would
cause trouble; but the purely mercantile operation
of getting a title to a product and then surrendering
it can be carried on as well in one place as in another.
The entrepreneur in his capacity of buyer and
seller does not even do the work which purchases and
sales involve. That is commonly done by agents.
Some of it, of course, may be done by the responsible
manager himself, and if that person is also the entrepreneur,
it follows that he does a part of the commercial labor
of his business. In this, however, he goes beyond
his function as entrepreneur. In that
capacity he does, as we have said, no labor of any
kind. Sales and purchases are made in his name,
but he does none of the work that leads up to them.
In the present study we do not need
to consider risks, inasmuch as the greater part
of them arise from dynamic causes; that is, from
the changes and disturbances to which the business
world is subject. An invention promises greatly
to cheapen the production of some article and,
for a time, to insure large returns for the men
who first utilize it. A capitalist may be
willing to take a risk for the sake of sharing
this gain; but in time both the risk and the gain
will vanish. The capacity of the new appliances
will have to be tested, a market for their output
found, etc. A small remainder of risk
is still entailed upon the capitalist if he leaves
his money in this business. The death of the managing
partner, the defaulting of payments for goods sold,
the chances of unwise or dishonest conduct on
the part of clerks or overseers, always impend
over a business, but these dangers are at a minimum
when the man who is at the head of the force of
managers has capital of his own in the business.
Risks are at a static level only when they are
thus reduced; and for our present purpose it is
best to consider that competition has eliminated
the establishments where any recklessness has
been shown in the management, and that the unavoidable
remainder of risk resolves itself, nearly enough for
practical purposes, into a deduction from the product
which the surviving establishments turn out in
a long period of time. A small percentage
of their annual gains, set aside for meeting unavoidable
losses, will make good these losses as they occur
and leave the businesses in a condition in which
they can yield as a steady return to owners of stock,
to lenders of further capital, and to laborers
all of their real product.
How the Entrepreneur contributes
to Production under Dynamic Conditions. - In
a dynamic state the entrepreneur emerges from
this passive position. He makes the supreme decisions
which now and again lead to changes in the business.
“Shall we adopt this new machine?” “Shall
we make this new product?” “Shall we enter
this new market?” are questions which are referred
to him, and on the decisions he reaches depends the
prospects of profit for the business. This activity
is not ordinary labor, but in a true sense it is a
productive activity, since it results in placing labor
and capital where they can produce more than they
have done and more than they could do were it not
for the enabling act of the entrepreneur which
places them on a vantage ground of superiority.
This subject will be discussed in a later chapter
and in connection with other phases of economic dynamics.
Values at a Static Level only when
Entrepreneurs’ Gains are Nil. - Any
net profit on an entrepreneur’s part means
that his product is selling for more than the elements
of it have cost him. But this is a condition
which, if labor and capital are as mobile as the static
hypothesis requires that they should be, will cause
this entrepreneur and others to move labor
and capital into his industry, thus increasing its
output and lowering the selling price of its product.
If there is no such action going on, it shows that
the entrepreneurs have no incentive for taking
it.
Values at a Static Level only when
the Gains of Labor in the Different Industries are
Equalized. - If labor is creating more
in one subgroup than in others, as it often is in
a dynamic condition, that fact means that some entrepreneurs
are making a profit, and, according to the principle
stated in the preceding paragraph, this means that
values are not at their static or “natural”
level. If, owing to new methods or to some other
cause, a given amount of labor in the subgroup
that produced the A’’’ of our table
creates an amount of that product which sells for
more than the B’’’ or the C’’’
which labor of like quantity makes, then the manufacturers
of A’’’ would obviously get a margin
of profit. They would not be obliged to pay for
labor any more than the market rate, and that, as we
shall see, cannot exceed what labor produces in the
groups B’’’ and C’’’.
In A’’’ the labor creates more and
the employer pockets the difference. In saying
this we assume one fact which we undertake later to
prove; namely, that there is a definite amount of
each product which can be attributed to labor alone
as its producer. Capital and labor work together,
but each is, in effect, the creator of a certain fraction
of their joint product.
Values Static only when the Gains
of Capital in Different Industries are Equalized. - If
capital is creating more in one industry than in another,
there is a margin of profit for the entrepreneurs
in the exceptionally productive industry. They
pay as interest on the capital they use only the market
rate, which is what equal amounts of capital can produce
and get elsewhere. If they produce more in the
one group, the entrepreneurs there can pocket
the excess as they did in the case of the product
of labor. We assume that there is everywhere a
definite product that can be attributed to capital
alone.
Values Normal when Moneys paid
out by Entrepreneurs equal Moneys Received. - In
the preceding paragraphs we have spoken of exchange
values as being static under certain conditions, but
we might have expressed the essential fact by saying
that prices are static under these conditions since
the money a product brings is a true expression of
its value. If A’’’ sells for
as many dollars as does B’’’, the
two things exchange for each other. In like manner
the product of labor and that of capital may be expressed
in terms of money, since the quantities of goods which
they respectively make sell for certain sums.
Wages and interest are nearly always conceived in
terms of money. The commercial mode of computing
costs of production and returns from production is
to translate them into moneys paid by entrepreneurs
and moneys received.
Costs of Production as related
to Static Incomes. - What to an entrepreneur
are costs are to workmen and capitalists incomes.
The one pays out wages and interest, and the others
get them; and these two sums are normal when together
they equal the prices received for goods produced.
The entrepreneur is the universal paymaster,
and in a static condition all incomes come from his
hand.