THE LAW OF INTEREST
The product of the final unit of labor - an
amount which in practice is measured without any tracing
of the previous growth of the working force - sets
the standard of the rate of wages. We have now
to see that the rate of interest has a similar basis;
and yet it is worth while to build up, wholly in imagination,
a fund of capital, just as we have made up the force
of laborers, increment by increment. This will
have the incidental effect of illustrating another
way in which wages may be determined.
Interest as a Residual Amount. - The
area BCD in our former figure represents the
difference between the total product of an industry
and the wages paid to laborers. If there is no
net profit accruing to the entrepreneur, this
area must represent interest. It is what is left
for the capitalist on the supposition that he and the
laborer together get all that there is. If the
goods sell for what they cost, this must be the fact,
and the amount represented by BCD has thus to
go to capital, since, by a rule of exclusion, it cannot
go to the entrepreneur nor to the laborer.
The mill and its contents earn for their operator
nothing but simple interest on the money they have
cost. Paying the laborers discharges the first
claim on the product, and there then remains only
enough of the product to pay the remaining claim,
that of capital.
The question still remains to be answered,
how the capitalist, if he is a different person from
the entrepreneur, or operator of the mill,
can make this functionary pay over to him all that
he has in his hands after paying the wages of labor.
The Importance of the Residuum. - The
above reasoning does not satisfactorily show what
influence the capitalist can use to make the entrepreneur
pay over to him the entire amount of the residuum.
It shows that after paying wages the entrepreneur
will have a certain amount left, but it is not thus
far clear how the capitalist can get it from him.
The fact that the laborers get only the amount represented
by ABDE and that the whole amount is ACDE
does, however, at least show that the entrepreneur
has the amount BCD left in his hands, and that
he is able to pay this amount to the capitalist
if by any appeal to competition the capitalist is able
to make him do it.
Interest not determined Residually. - The
fact is that the interest on capital is fixed exactly
as are the wages of labor.
We will let another figure represent
the entire product of the same amount of labor and
the same amount of capital that were represented in
the former case. We will assume that there is
at the outset a complete force of laborers, and that
no men are added to it or taken from it; but we will
gradually introduce units of capital instead of units
of labor as in the former case. The amount of
capital is now represented by the line A’E’
and the product of the first unit of it by the line
A’C’. The product of the successive
units declines along the curve C’D’.
The final unit of capital then brings into existence
the amount of wealth represented by E’D’.
As every other unit now produces the same amount,
the capital as a whole creates the quantity represented
by A’B’D’E’ and every
unit of it makes its own separate contribution to
that amount. In this we have simply applied to
capital and its earnings the principle we formerly
applied to labor and its earnings.
General Form of the Law of Final
Productivity. - This principle is the
law of final productivity, one of those universal principles
which govern economic life in all its stages of evolution.
Either one of the two agents of industry, used in
increasing quantities in connection with a fixed amount
of the other agent, is subject to a law of diminishing
returns. The final unit of the increasing agent
produces less than did the earlier units in the series.
This does not mean that at any one time one unit produces
less than another, for at any one time all are equally
productive. It means that the tenth unit produces
less than the ninth did when there were only nine
in use, and that the ninth unit formerly produced
less than the eighth did in that still earlier stage
of the process in which there were only eight in
use, etc. If the productive wealth of the United
States were only five hundred dollars per capita instead
of more than twice that amount, interest would be
higher than it is, because the productive power of
every dollar’s worth of capital would be more
than the productive power of each dollar’s worth
is now; and, on the other hand, if we continue to
pile up fortunes, great and small, till there are
in the country two thousand dollars for every man,
woman, and child of the population, interest will
fall, because the productive power of a dollar’s
worth will become less than it now is.
How Competition fixes Interest. - We
can now see how it is that the capitalist can make
the entrepreneur pay over to him the amount
left in his hands after paying wages. Every unit
of capital that any one offers for hire has a productive
power. It can call into existence a certain amount
of goods. The offer of it to any entrepreneur
is virtually an offer of a fresh supply of the kinds
of goods which he is making for sale. Loaning
ten thousand dollars to a woolen manufacturer is really
selling him the amount of cloth that ten thousand dollars
put into his equipment will bring into existence.
Loaning a hundred thousand dollars to the manufacturer
of steel, so as to enable him in some way to perfect
his equipment, is virtually selling him the number
of additional tons of steel, ingots, or rails that
he can make by virtue of this accession to his plant.
The Significance of Free Competition. - Now,
the tender of capital may be made to any entrepreneur
in a particular industry, and the existence of free
competition between these entrepreneurs implies
that a lender of capital can get from one or another
of them the whole value of the product that this capital
is able to create. A unit of capital in the steel
business can produce n tons of steel in a year,
and if one employer will not pay the price of n
tons for the loan of it, another will. This,
indeed, implies an absolutely free competition; but
that is the condition of the problem we have first
to solve. When we know what ideally active competition
will do, we can measure the effects of the obstructions
that, in practice, competition actually encounters.
Competition for Capital among Different
Industries. - The capitalist can invoke
the aid of competition outside of the limits of one
particular business. He may offer his loan to
steel makers, to woolen manufacturers, cotton spinners,
silk weavers, shoemakers, etc. Within each
one of these industries perfect competition between
the different employers will give him the value of
the product which, in that business, his capital is
able to create. If, however, what in this way
he offers to men in one occupation is worth more than
what he offers to men in another line, - if
capital is worth more to steel makers than it is to
cotton spinners, - he will find a market for
his capital in the former industry; and this process
of seeking out the employment in which capital is
the more productive and there bestowing the loans of
capital, will go on until every such local excess of
productive power is removed and capital can produce
as much wealth in one business as it can in another.
Everywhere capital will then be both producing and
receiving the same amount, and general interest will
everywhere be determined by the final productivity
principle acting all through the business world.
When Interest as Directly Determined
equals Interest as Residually Measured. - The
area BCD of the first figure measures what the
entrepreneur has left after paying wages.
This amount and no more he can pay as interest, and
he will pay it if he has to. The area A’B’D’E’
of the second figure represents what he must pay as
interest; and we can now see that, if competition is
perfectly free, this amount equals the amount BCD
of the first figure. If, after paying wages,
there is any more left in the entrepreneur’s
hands than competition compels him to pay out as interest,
he is realizing a net profit; he is selling his goods
for more than they cost him, and this, as we saw at
the outset, is a condition that under perfect competition
cannot continue. The natural price of goods is
the cost price. If the market price of anything
is in excess of cost, entrepreneurs receive
a profit, and in order to do more business and make
a larger aggregate of such profit they bring new labor
and capital into their industry. The increased
output lowers prices, and the excess of gain is thus
taken from the entrepreneur. If BCD
is smaller than A’B’D’E’,
the entrepreneur incurs a loss and will curtail
his business and let some labor and capital go where
they can produce more.
Taking this remainder of income from
the entrepreneur by means of an addition to
the output of goods and a reduction of the price of
them does not annihilate the income, but bestows it
on other recipients; for the reduction in price which
destroys an employer’s profit can come only
in a way that benefits consumers. It means that
enlarged production of which we have just spoken,
which scatters more goods throughout the community
and insures an addition to the real incomes of both
laborers and permanent investors.
Effect of Perfect Mobility of Labor
and Capital. - Perfect mobility of labor
and capital insures that the residuum in the entrepreneur’s
hands after wages are paid shall all be made over to
the capitalist. We encounter here again the static
law that, with competition working without let or
hindrance, the entrepreneur as such can keep
nothing for himself; though if he is also a worker
he will get wages, and if he is also a capitalist
he will get interest. His business will pay wages
on all kinds of labor, including that of management,
and interest on all capital, including his own.
A net gain above all this it will not afford, and
whatever the entrepreneur has left after paying
wages he will have to use in paying interest, and vice
versa. Laborers and owners of capital have,
as it were, to take each others’ leavings.
Such is the situation in an ideally static condition,
though we shall see how it is changed in actual and
progressive society.
The area BCD of the first figure
is, under static conditions, exactly equal to the
area A’B’D’E’ of the
second figure, because ACDE represents the
whole product, BCD in the first figure represents
all that is left of it after wages, measured by ABDE,
are paid; and we know by evidence both theoretical
and practical that the capitalist, whose share is
directly expressed by A’B’D’E’
of the second figure, can claim and get the whole
of this amount.
Wages as a Residuum. - It
is clear that the same reasoning applies to wages.
In the second figure they are represented as a residuum.
The area B’C’D’ represents
what the entrepreneur has left after paying
interest, and nobody can get this amount but the wage
earner. The reason, however, why the wage earner
can get it is that free competition will give him
the amount ABDE of the first figure, and this,
under perfectly static conditions, must equal B’C’D’
of the second. Under perfect competition the
entrepreneur cannot have any of the amount
B’C’D’ left in his hands after
meeting the claims that the wage earner makes on him.
On the other hand, he must have enough left to pay
interest, since otherwise he would be incurring a loss,
and that could not fail to force him and others who
are in the same situation to contract their operations
or go out of business. If the output of goods
is reduced, either by the retirement of some employers
or the curtailment of product by all, the price of
what continues to be sold will be raised to the point
at which wages and interest can be paid.
Wages and Interest both adjusted
at Social Margins of Production. - It
is to be noted that wages and interest are fixed at
the social margin of production, which means that they
equal what labor and capital respectively can produce
by adding themselves to the forces already at work
in the general field of employment. In making
the supposition that, owing to some disturbing fact,
a particular entrepreneur has not enough after
paying wages to pay interest, we assume that the rate
of interest is fixed, in this way, in the general
field and not merely in his establishment.
If B’C’D’
were larger than ABDE, the entrepreneur
would be selling goods for more than cost and realizing
a net profit, which he cannot do in a static state;
but a pure profit is not only possible but actual
in a dynamic state.
In actual business total returns represented
by ACDE amount to more than the sum represented
by ABDE (wages) plus A’B’D’E’
(interest). There are conditions that in practical
life are continually bringing this to pass in different
lines of business, though not in all of them at once.
The real world is dynamic and therefore the true net
profit, or the share of the entrepreneur in
the strict sense of the term, is a positive quantity.
This income is always determined residually. It
is a remainder and nothing else. It is what is
left when wages and interest are paid out of the general
product. To the entrepreneur comes the
price of the products that an industry creates.
Out of this he pays wages and interest, and very often
he has something remaining. There is no way of
determining this profit except as a remainder.
The return from the sale of the product is a positive
amount fixed by the final utility principle.
Wages and interest are positive amounts, and each
of them is fixed by the final productivity principle.
The difference between the first amount and the sum
of the two others is profit, and it is never determined
in any other way than by subtracting outgoes from
a gross income. It is the only share in distribution
that is so determined. Entrepreneur’s
profits and residual income are synonymous terms.
In the static state no such residual income exists,
but from a dynamic society it is never absent.
Every entrepreneur makes some profits or losses,
and in society as a whole the profits greatly predominate.
Summary of Facts concerning a Static
Adjustment of Wages. - We know then that
in any industry wages and interest absorb the whole
product, because any deviation from that rule in a
particular group is corrected in the way above mentioned.
Moreover, general wages and interest, as determined
by the law of final productivity, must equal those
incomes when they are determined residually. The
area of the rectangular portion of one of the foregoing
figures must equal the area of the three-sided part
of the other. The question arises why all entrepreneurs
might not get a uniform profit at once. This would
not lure any labor or capital from one group or subgroup
to another. If, after paying wages and interest
at market rates, the entrepreneurs in each
industry have anything left, the entire labor and
capital are producing more than they get and there
is an inducement to managers and capitalists to withdraw
from their present employers and become entrepreneurs
on their own account. Such an entrepreneur
entering the field, drawing marginal labor and capital
away from the entrepreneurs who are already
there and combining them in a new establishment, can
make them produce more than he will have to pay them
and pocket the difference. If such a condition
were realized, there would be a gain in starting new
enterprises, since luring away marginal agents and
combining them in new establishments would always
be profitable. When we introduce into the problem
dynamic elements we shall see that centralization,
which makes shops larger instead of smaller, makes
industries more productive, and that what happens
when net profits appear is more often the enlarging
of one establishment than the creation of new ones.
Entrepreneurs in the large establishments can
afford to resist the effort made by others to lure
away any of the labor or capital which they are employing,
and they will do this for the sake of retaining their
profits. They can do it by bidding against each
other, in case any of them are making additions to
their mills or shops, and also by bidding against
any new employers who may appear. Perfect competition
requires that this bidding for labor and capital shall
continue up to the profit-annihilating point.
Here, as elsewhere in the purely static part of the
discussion, we have to make assumptions that are rigorously
theoretical and put out of view in a remorseless way
disturbing elements which appear in real life.
The static state requires that all entrepreneurs
who survive the sharp tests of competition should
have equally productive establishments, which means
that they should all be able to get the same amount
of product from a given amount of labor and capital.
The actual fact is that differences of productive
power still survive. There are some small establishments
which, within the little spheres in which they act,
are as productive as large ones; but there are also
some which are struggling hopelessly against large
rivals in the general market and are destined erelong
to give up the contest. In other words, the centralizing
and leveling effects of competition are approximated
but never completely realized in actual life.
A fact that it is well to note is
that the test of final productivity is inaccurately
made when unduly large amounts of labor and capital
are made the basis of the measurement. Take away,
for instance, a quarter of the working force, estimate
the reduction of the product which this withdrawal
occasions, and attribute this loss entirely to the
labor which has been taken away, and you estimate it
too highly. With so large a section of the labor
withdrawn the capital would work at a disadvantage,
and a part of the reduction of the product would be
due to this fact. If we should take away all the
labor, the capital would be completely paralyzed,
and the product would become nil. It would
obviously be inaccurate to say that the whole product
is attributable to the labor, on the ground that withdrawing
the labor annihilates it all. With any large
part of the labor treated as a single unit, the loss
of product occasioned by a withdrawal of such a unit
is more than can be accurately imputed to it as its
specific product. The smaller the increments
or units are made, the less important is this element
of inaccuracy, and it becomes a wholly negligible
quantity when they become very small. A study
of the forms of the productivity curves will show
that if we take as the increment of labor used in
making the test only a tenth of the whole force, we
exaggerate the product imputable to it by a very minute
fraction, say by less than a one-hundredth part; and
if we take a hundredth of the labor as a final unit,
we exaggerate the product that is solely attributable
to it by an amount so minute that it is of no consequence
in practice or in any theory that tries to be applicable
to practice.
A question may be raised as to whether
we are correct in saying that the entrepreneur’s
profit is residual, in view of the fact that the entire
product of a business is at the mercy of the management,
so that a bad manager may reduce it or a good one
may increase it. It may be further claimed that
that part of the management of a business which consists
in making the most far-reaching decisions cannot safely
be intrusted to a salaried superintendent or other
paid official and must get its returns, if at all,
in the form of profits. Even in this case the
gains are secured by making the gross return, which
is the minuend in the case, large, leaving the two
subtrahends, wages and interest, unchanged, and thus
creating a remainder or residuum. We shall later
see to what extent entrepreneurs do in fact
create the profits that come to them.
The complete static conception of
society requires that no entrepreneur should
be left in the field who cannot continue indefinitely
to hold his own against the competition of his rivals,
and this requires essential equality of productive
power on the part of all of them. It is not necessary,
however, that all should operate upon an equal scale
of magnitude, for an interesting feature of modern
life is the need of many small productive establishments
that cater to local demands and to wants which, without
being local, call for only a few articles of a kind.
Repairs, small orders, and peculiar orders are executed
more cheaply in small establishments, and they survive
under the very rule of essential equality of productive
power which static conditions require. For catering
to the general market and producing staple goods the
large establishment has a decisive advantage, and
this insures the centralization which is the marked
feature of recent industrial life.