RENT
The Term “Rent” as
Historically Used. - The word rent
has a striking history. The science of political
economy first took shape in a country in which direct
employers of labor were not, as a rule, the owners
of much land. Farmers, merchants, and many manufacturers
hired land and furnished only the auxiliary capital
which was necessary in order to utilize it. In
a practical way the earnings of land were thus separated
from those of capital in other forms, since they went
to a different class of persons; and in the thought
of the people the charges made for the use of mere
ground came to constitute a unique kind of income.
If, during the last century, the land in England had
been a highly mercantile commodity, and if it had been
the common practice of entrepreneurs not to
hire it but to buy and own it, as they bought and
owned all other industrial instruments, there is little
probability that land would have been considered, either
in practical thought or in science, as a thing to
be as broadly distinguished as it has been from all
other capital goods. A business man would have
measured his permanent fund of capital in pounds sterling
and would have included in the amount whatever he had
invested in land. As in America any representation
of the capital of a corporation includes the sums
invested in every productive way, and this includes
the value of all land that the company holds, so in
England, under a similar system of conducting business,
any statement of the amount of a particular business
capital would have included the whole of the productive
wealth embarked in the enterprise; and in any statement
of the forms of it there would have appeared, besides
a list of all tools, buildings, unfinished goods,
and the like, a schedule of the prices of land that
the company owned and used. In “putting
capital into his business” a man might buy land,
in “withdrawing his capital” he might
sell it; and the land in the interim would be the
obvious embodiment of this part of his fund. The
fact, then, that land was owned by one class of persons
and let to another for hire, and that the lessees
were the entrepreneurs or users of it, caused
practical thought and speech to put land in a class
by itself.
The Origin of the Theory of Rent. - Scientific
thought powerfully strengthened this tendency.
At a very early date a formula was attained for measuring
the rent of land, while no satisfactory formula was,
then or for a long time afterward, discovered for measuring
the amount of interest. Men contented themselves
with saying that the rate of interest depends on demand
and supply. In the case of the rent of land the
same thing might have been said, but here such a statement
was not mentally satisfying, and investigators tried
to ascertain why demand and supply so act as to fix
the income that land yields at a certain definable
amount.
The Traditional Formula for Rent. - The
formula which has long been accepted as measuring
the rent of a piece of land, though it bears the name
of Ricardo, grew into shape under the hands of several
earlier writers. In its best form of statement
this principle asserts that “the rent of a piece
of land is the product that can be realized by applying
labor and capital to it, minus the product that can
be realized by applying the same amount of labor and
capital to land of the poorest grade that is in cultivation
at all.” The quantity of the poorest land
must be left indefinite, and all that the given amount
of labor and capital can economically utilize must
be left at their disposal. It would not do to
say that the rent of an acre of good land equals
its product less that of an acre of the poorest
land in cultivation tilled with the same expenditure
of labor and capital. If we should select a bit
of wheat land in England tilled at a large outlay
in the way of work, fertilizers, drains, etc.,
and try the experiment of putting the same amount
of labor and capital on a piece of equal size in the
remotest part of Canada, we should find that, so far
from securing wheat enough to pay the bills that we
should incur in the way of wages and interest, we
should not have enough to help us greatly in the defraying
of these costs, and the cultivation of this piece
of land would be a losing venture. Instead of
being no-rent land, yielding merely wages and interest
for the labor and capital used in connection with
it, it would be minus-rent land, deducting something
from the earnings which the agents combined with it
might elsewhere secure. In order to utilize such
land at all, one must till it in what is termed an
extensive rather than an intensive way, putting a
small amount rather than a large amount of work and
expenditure on it. By tilling ten acres of a remote
and sterile farm with as much labor and other outlay
as a very good acre of land in England receives, one
can perhaps get enough to pay the required wages and
interest. In general no-rent land is commonly
utilized in an extensive way and very good land in
an intensive way; and in stating the old formula for
rent we need to be careful to make it mean that the
rent of the good piece is its total product less the
product that can be had by taking from the good piece
the labor and capital it now absorbs and setting them
at work on a piece of the poorest land which is enough
larger than the good one to enable us to secure a crop
which will be worth just the amount of wages and interest
we must pay. The larger size of the poor piece
of land is an essential condition.
Real Significance of Rent Formula. - It
will be seen that this formula amounts to saying that
the rent of land is what the land itself adds to the
marginal product of labor and capital. Put a
certain amount of labor and capital on a piece of land
of good quality, and you get a certain amount of product.
Withdraw the land from the combination, and you force
the labor and capital to become marginal increments
of these agents. They must go elsewhere and get
what they can. One alternative that is open to
them is that of seeking out land of a grade so poor
that it has not been previously utilized and doing
what they can to get a product out of it. Whatever
they can make such land yield is, in an economic sense,
wholly their own product. There is an indefinite
quantity of this kind of land to be had, and wherever
labor and capital utilize any part of it, they can
have all that they produce. Now if we subtract
what they there create from what was created when
they were working on the good land, we have the rent
of that land.
Rent as a Product Imputable to
Land. - The difference between what the
labor and capital produce at the margin of cultivation
of land and what they can produce on good land, or
land that lies within the margin, is clearly attributable
to the qualities of the land itself. Given X
units of labor and Y units of capital, combine
with them no land except such as is too poor to have
been previously utilized, and you get a certain product.
It is the product of the labor and capital using something
which is free to any one. Now put a piece of
good land into the combination; to the X units
of labor and Y units of capital add a piece
of productive land and see what you can create.
We do this by taking these units of labor and capital
away from the worthless marginal land and setting
them to tilling that which is of the better quality.
The product is of course larger than they got before,
and the difference measures what the land itself adds
to the output of the other agents in the combination.
The true conception of rent is that of the specific
addition which land makes to the product of other
agents used in connection with it. There are
various ways of measuring this addition, but the method
just used will at least show that the presence of
the good land is the cause of the excess of product
which given amounts of labor and capital secure over
what they could create on land of the poorest quality.
Rent as a Differential Product. - In
the early statements of the rent law it was not said
that the rent of a piece of land is the product specifically
attributable to it. If it had been, the chances
are large that a much broader and more scientific
use of the rent formula would have resulted.
The law of rent, as it was actually stated, made it
consist of a differential amount. It was what
a given amount of labor and capital would produce
under one set of conditions minus what they would
produce under another. Since it is the presence
or the absence of the productive land which makes
the only difference between the two conditions, rent,
even as it is thus defined, is really the amount of
product specifically attributable to the land.
It is what is created when the land is used in excess
of what would be created if it were not used and if
the cooeperating agents did the best they could without
it. We may use, as the most general formula for
the rent of land, the contribution which land itself
makes to the product of social industry.
If we use the same method in measuring
the rent of land which we used in measuring the wages
of labor and the returns of capital, we shall represent
the rent of a given piece of land as the sum of a series
of differential amounts. In the accompanying
figure the vertical belts bounded by lines rising
from the letters A, B, C, etc.,
represent the products realized by applying successive
increments of labor and capital to a given piece of
land; and the horizontal lines running toward the
left from A’, B’, C’,
etc., separate the wages and interest from the
amounts that are successively added to rent.
When one composite unit of labor and capital is working,
its product and its pay is measured by the belt between
the line AA’ and the line NN’.
A second composite unit produces the amount represented
by the area between AA’ and BB’,
and that is the amount which each unit separately
considered will produce and get as its pay. This
leaves the area between the horizontal line running
from B’ and the section of the descending
curve as the rent of the land. A third unit of
labor and capital produces what is represented by the
area between BB’ and CC’,
and this becomes the standard of pay for all units,
leaving the enlarged area above the horizontal line
at C’ as rent. In the end there
are ten units of labor and capital. Their total
earnings are expressed by the area of the rectangle
below the horizontal line running from J’,
and the sum of all the areas above that line is rent.
The Intensive Margin of Cultivation. - The
extensive margin of cultivation is the land that is
adjacent to an imaginary boundary line separating
the grades of land that are good enough to be used
from those that are too poor to be used. There
is, however, what may be called the intensive margin
of cultivation. A given bit of land is said to
be cultivated more and more intensively when more and
more labor and capital are used on it. Land is
subject to what is called the law of diminishing returns.
Law of Diminishing Returns. - The
more labor and capital you employ on a given piece
of land, the less you will get as a product for each
unit of these agents. What the last unit of labor
adds to the antecedent output is less than was added
by any of the other units, and the same is true of
the last unit of capital. As we continue the
process of enlarging the working force and adding to
the working appliances, we reach a point at which
it is better to cease putting new men with their equipment
at work on this piece of land and to set them working
on a bit of land so poor that it was not formerly
utilized at all. We may assume here that what
a man needs, in the way of auxiliary capital, goes
with him, whether he joins a force that is working
on good land or migrates to a less productive region.
He will go if it will pay him to do it. In this
way we make a sort of dual unit of labor and capital
and apply a series of such units to land.
Ground Capital and Auxiliary Capital
Distinguished. - Land itself is a component
part of the permanent fund of productive wealth to
which we have given the generic name capital.
It differs from other capital goods in that it does
not wear out and require renewing. Working appliances,
however, as they wear out and are replaced, constitute
a permanent fund of auxiliary capital, and we shall
apply this term to the abiding stock of such instruments
except in connections in which the adjective is not
needed, because it is clear that the land, or ground
capital, cannot be referred to. In dynamic studies
the distinction between land and auxiliary capital
becomes very important.
How the Intensive Margin locates
the Extensive One. - The labor and the
auxiliary capital that betake themselves to new land
of the inferior quality represent an overflow from
the better land. As long as men can do as well
by staying where they are as they can by migrating
to new regions, where inferior lands are to be had,
they will stay; but when they incur a loss by staying,
they move. What a laborer can create by securing
the use of an equipment and adding himself to the
force that is at work on some good farm, can be approximately
estimated; and if there is somewhere a piece of land
not thus far used to which he can remove, and if,
by going to work upon it, he can create any more than
he created while working on the older farm and taking
his products as his pay, he will till that poor piece.
But neither he nor any one else will till a piece that
is still less productive. If any one were to
set himself working on land of still poorer quality,
he would lose and not gain by the change, since there
he would produce even less than he can when he is the
last man set working on the good piece.
To what Extent the Movement of
Labor and that of Capital are Interdependent. - The
early statements of the law of rent did not usually
define the intensive margin of cultivation in connection
with labor and capital separately, but spoke of these
two agents as employed together upon land in quantities
increasing up to a limit beyond which both labor and
capital would best be employed elsewhere. The
supposition that labor and capital go thus together
from one grade of land to another is only approximately
accurate. If we consider one man and five hundred
dollars’ worth of productive wealth as a dual
unit of labor and capital, and add such units, one
after another, to the forces at work on a tract of
good land, we shall reach a point at which it will
not be profitable to increase the amount of one of
the agents, while it will still be profitable to increase
the amount of the other. It will perhaps not
pay to use any more capital, but it may still pay
to add to the number of workers. On land that
is tilled more and more intensively, labor and capital
are not tied together in fixed proportions in such
a way that, when there is more of one of them used,
there is proportionately more of the other.
Moreover, when a unit of one of them abandons a piece
of land and goes elsewhere, there is no probability
that exactly one unit of the other will do the same.
There is, indeed, no such thing as a dual unit of
labor and capital that can be thought of as moving
to and fro among different employments till it finds
the point at which, as a dual unit, it can create
its largest product. These two agents so locate
themselves that a final unit of each one, separately
considered, produces as much where it is as it can
produce anywhere else.
It is, however, to be noted that the
amount of labor that can profitably be employed on
a piece of land grows larger the more capital there
is employed in connection with it. An acre of
land and a thousand dollars’ worth of auxiliary
funds can enable more men to get good returns than
can an acre combined with a fund of five hundred dollars.
Conversely, the more men there are working on the area,
the more auxiliary capital it pays to use there.
If there are five men working on a small field it
may be that a thousand dollars may be well invested
in aiding them, while with only one man it would not
pay to use so large an amount. The capital and
the labor, as it were, attract each other. Additional
capital attracts further labor, and vice versa,
till a condition is reached in which neither of them
can so well be used on that particular piece of land
as it can elsewhere. Each one has then been used
on this area up to its own intensive-marginal limit.
So also when one of these agents betakes itself to
marginal land, it attracts the other agent thither.
When there are ten men on the poorest piece of land
in a locality, it is possible to make a considerable
amount of capital at that point pay the return generally
prevailing, whereas only a small amount would pay
it if there were only five men working. With a
thousand dollars invested on that land more laborers
will be lured thither by the prospect of fair returns
than would be lured thither if there were only half
as much capital. The general apportionment of
both agents tends to be such that a unit of either
is as well off on one piece of land as on another,
and each is as well off at the extensive margin of
cultivation of land as it is on the intensive margin.
Labor and Capital combined in Varying
Amounts. - The amount of capital that
is combined with a unit of labor is not often the same
on good land as it is on poor. The proportions
in which labor and capital will be combined on the
marginal field will be almost certain to vary from
those in which they were combined in the better field
from which they came. It may be that they leave
industries in which an average man uses an equipment
worth a thousand dollars. When they reach the
margin of cultivation, capital may be so scarce that
the thousand dollars will not stay in the hands of
the one man but will divide itself among several.
The General Law of the Extension
of the Margin of Cultivation. - Sometimes,
when labor moves to new land that is now at the margin,
it takes its new equipment with it; but such land is
not always tilled by independent settlers. Employing
farmers may set men working on it and pay them all
that they produce; and the farmers may furnish the
men with capital of their own or borrow capital for
them to use. In either case a static condition
requires the equalizing of the productivity of labor
at the intensive margin with that of labor at the
extensive margin; and it requires a similar leveling
of the productivity of capital at the two margins.
When this leveling has taken place in both cases,
the all-around marginal product of labor fixes the
rate of wages, and that of capital fixes the rate of
interest. What a man creates on the good land
and with the adequate capital, or on poor land with
proportionate capital, - in any occupation
on land of either grade, - determines the
pay that he and other men can get. It constitutes
in itself the wages of labor. In so far as the
overflow of labor and capital into any one limited
region of marginal land is concerned, the full statement
is this: that the margin of utilization of land
will be extended to the point at which a unit of labor,
using as much of the marginal land as it is economical
to use, and such amount of auxiliary capital as is
economical to combine with this unit of labor and
the land it occupies, will create a product equal
to the wages of the unit of labor as they are determined
by the product it created when it was employed on the
good land and in connection with the full equipment
of auxiliary capital.
The Rent of a Fund of Capital. - We
saw that one unit of labor employed in connection
with a given amount of capital produces more than
does a second; that the second produces more than the
third; and that, if we continue to supply units one
at a time, the last unit in the series produces the
least of all. Wages are fixed by the amount that
one unit of labor produces when the working force is
complete, and that is what is contributed to the general
product by the unit of labor which comes last in the
imaginary series by which the force is built up.
Owing to the more favorable conditions under which,
in their time, the earlier units worked, they were
able to produce surpluses above the amount produced
by the last one. When they entered the field
they were supplied with excessive amounts of capital.
The first one had the whole fund cooeperating with
it, till it had to share it with the second; and after
that each had a half of it till they had to share
evenly with a third, etc. We have seen that
all the surpluses appearing in connection with the
earlier units are attributable in reality to capital.
The area BCD (page 139) represents the amount
by which the presence of an excess of capital increases
the products attributable to the earlier units of
labor. It represents the sum of all the differences
between the products of the earlier units and the
product of that final one which in the end sets the
standard of productivity of labor. It might be
called the rent of the fund of capital. It is
composed of a sum of differences exactly like those
which constitute the rent of a piece of land.
The Rent of a Permanent Force of
Labor. - In the figure on page 148, the
working force was supposed to be fixed in amount, the
capital increasing by increments, or as some earlier
economists would have said, by “doses”
along the line A’E’. The last
unit of capital produces the amount D’E’,
and all the capital produces A’B’D’E’,
while products of the earlier units of capital, as
they come successively into the field and are used
by an excessively large labor force, are represented
by the area B’C’D’. Here
this area represents what may be called the rent of
the force of labor, since it is a sum of surpluses
that, again, are entirely akin to those that constitute
the rent of a piece of land.
A Question of Nomenclature. - It
may be an open question, as a matter of mere nomenclature,
whether these surpluses which are thus traceable to
a permanent fund of capital, on the one hand, and to
a permanent force of labor, on the other, can with
advantage be called rents. In this treatise we
do not think it best to employ that nomenclature.
What is not uncertain is that these gains are measurable
by the same formula that measures the rent of a piece
of land. If the essential thing about rent were
that it is a material product and consists of a sum
of differential quantities, these incomes certainly
would be rents. Popular thought, however, attaches
another meaning to this term, and we therefore limit
ourselves to saying that these differential incomes
or surpluses may be determined in amount by the principle
of rent. They can be described and measured exactly
as the Ricardians described the income of landlords.
This surplus is an effect on a man himself.
It is not anything outward or tangible. It
exists only in the man’s sensations, and
is as far as possible from being a concrete income
in material form traceable to some particular agent.
It can be measured and described in ways that are
quite akin to the manner in which the product
of land is measured and described. Each consists
of the sum of a series of surpluses or differential
amounts, and each, moreover, represents a gain
which is not offset by any corresponding subjective
cost. The rent of land must be paid by an
entrepreneur and is a cost in the same
sense in which wages and interest are so; but
the owner of the land did not create it by personal
effort or sacrifice.
Analogies between the product of land,
or rent, and the special gains of consumers from
the more important parts of their consumption
do exist, but they are overbalanced by essential
differences; and it is better to use the term rent
only in describing the specific contribution to the
material product of industry which a concrete and
material agent makes.