ECONOMIC DYNAMICS
The Efficiency of Static Forces
in Dynamic Societies. - The static state
which has thus far been kept in view is a hypothetical
one, for there is no actual society which is not changing
its form and the character of its activities.
Five organic changes, which we shall soon study, are
going on in every economic society; and yet the striking
fact is that, in spite of this, a civilized society
usually has, at each particular date, a shape that
conforms in some degree to the one which, under the
conditions existing at that date, the static forces
acting alone would give to it. It is even true
that, as long as competition is free, the most active
societies conform most closely to their static models.
If we could check the five radical changes that are
going on in a society that is very full of energy, - if,
as it were, we could stop such an organism midway
in its career of rapid growth and let it lapse into
a stationary condition, - the shape that
it would take would be not radically unlike the one
which it had when we interposed the check on its progress.
Taking on the theoretically static form would not
strikingly alter its actual shape. The actual
form of a highly dynamic society hovers relatively
near to its static model though it never conforms
to it. In the case of sluggish societies this
would not be true; for if in one of them we stopped
the forces of growth and waited long enough to let
the static influences produce their full effects,
the shape to which they would bring the organism would
be very different from the one which it actually had
when its slow progress was brought to a stop.
Most efficient in the most changeful societies are
forces which, if they were acting by themselves alone,
would produce a changeless state. The reasons
for this will later appear.
Differences between Static Forms
of Society at Different Dates. - A highly
dynamic condition, then, is one in which the economic
organism changes rapidly and yet, at any time in the
course of its changes, is relatively near to a certain
static model. It is clear, therefore, that it
cannot, at different periods, conform even approximately
to one single model. If the forces of change
which in 1800 were impelling the industrial society
of America to a forward movement had been suppressed,
and if competition had been ideally free and active,
that society would before long have settled into the
shape then required by the forces which, in the preceding
chapters, we have described. Some labor would
have moved from certain occupations to others and gained
by the change; and this movement of labor would have
ended by making the productive power and the pay of
a unit of this agent uniform in all the different
subgroups of the system. Capital would have so
apportioned itself as to level out inequalities in
its earning power. The profits of entrepreneurs
would have been equalized by becoming in all cases
nil, and the best available methods of production
would everywhere be found surviving and bestowing
their entire fruits on laborers and capitalists.
All this is involved in saying that the static model,
the form of which was determined by the conditions
of 1800, would have been realized. This would
have been brought about by suppressing at that date
the forces which cause organic change and by giving
to competition a perfectly unobstructed field.
If we had done this in 1900, instead of at the earlier
date, economic society would, in a like way, have
conformed to the shape required by the conditions
of 1900; and this would have been very different from
the shape which the static forces would have given
to society a century earlier. There is an ideal
static shape for every period, and no two of these
static shapes are alike.
Differences between the Actual
Shape of Society and the Static One at Any One Time. - The
actual shape of society at any one time is not the
static model of that time; but it tends to conform
to it, and in a very dynamic society is more nearly
like it than it would be in one in which the forces
of change are less active. With all the transforming
influences to which American industrial society is
subject, it to-day conforms more closely to a normal
form than do the more conservative societies of Europe
and far more closely than do the sluggish societies
of Asia. A viscous liquid in a vessel may show
a surface that is far from level; but a highly fluid
substance will come nearly to a level, even though
we shake the vessel containing it vigorously enough
to create waves on the surface and currents throughout
the whole mass. This is a fair representation
of a society in a highly dynamic condition. Its
very activities tend to bring it nearer to its static
model than it would be if its constituent materials
were not fluid and if it were never agitated.
The static shape itself, though it is never completely
copied in the actual shape of society, is for scientific
purposes a reality. There are powerful influences
tending to force the industrial organization at every
point to conform to it. The level of the sea
is a reality, though the motion of the waters never
subsides sufficiently to make their surface accurately
conform to it. As vigorously agitated, the water
shows a surface that is nearer to the ideal level
than would an ocean of mud, tar, or other sluggishly
flowing stuff. The winds throw up waves a few
feet high, but the fluidity keeps the general surface
surprisingly level; and so civilized society, made
as it is of fluid material kept in vigorous agitation,
finds, as it were, its level easily. If in any
year we could and should stop the dynamic disturbances,
the economic society would assume the static shape
which the conditions of that year called for as readily
as the sea would find its normal level if winds and
tides should completely cease. Static influences
that draw society forever toward its natural form
are always fundamental, and progress has no tendency
to suppress them.
Competition a Cause of Rapid Changes
in the Standard Shape of Society and of a Quick Conformity
of the Actual Shape to the Standard One. - The
competition which is active enough to change the standard
shape of society rapidly - that, for example,
which spurs on mechanical invention and causes a large
profit to be realized in a particular subgroup - has
also the effect of calling labor and capital quickly
to the point at which the profit appears, and, in
the absence of any monopoly, reduces this profit to
nil and restores, in so far as this cause of
disturbance goes, the equilibrium of the groups.
Under the influence of active competition a particular
group frequently undergoes quick changes which call
for more labor and capital, but it gets them quickly;
and, as has just been said, the standard shape of
a society which is in this highly fluid condition does
not differ so much from the actual shape as does that
of a society the movements of which are sluggish.
The standard shape is like the hare that moves quickly
and irregularly; while the actual shape is like the
pursuing hound, which moves equally quickly, follows
closely all turns of the course, and, if the game
were to stop moving, would in short order close on
it.
The Equalization of the Productive
Power of Labor and of Capital in the Different Subgroups. - We
have seen that in a static state labor and capital
do not move from subgroup to subgroup in the system,
and that this absence of flow in a fluid body is not
brought about by monopoly or by any approach to it.
That, indeed, would obstruct transfers of the producing
agents from point to point; but monopoly is a thing
most rigorously excluded by the static hypothesis.
At every point we have assumed that the power to move
is absolute, while only the motive is lacking.
The equalization of the productive power of labor
in the various subgroups precludes the migration of
labor, and a like equalization precludes a migration
of capital.
Equalization of Productive Powers
within the Subgroups. - Not merely must
each unit of labor or of capital be able to create
as much wealth in one subgroup as in another, but
within the subgroup - the specific industry - each
unit must be able to create as much under one employer
within the industry as under another. The different
entrepreneurs must compete with each other
on terms of equality, and no one of them must be able
to wrest from a rival any part of the rival’s
patronage. So long as one competitor has an advantage
over another in his mode of creating a product, there
is no equilibrium within the subgroup. The more
efficient user of labor and capital is able to draw
away labor and capital from the less efficient one,
and the self-seeking impulse which is at the basis
of competition impels him to do it. The producer
who works at the greater advantage is foreordained
to underbid and supplant the one who works under more
unfavorable conditions. That a static state may
exist and that the movements of labor and capital
from point to point may be precluded, every competitor
within a subgroup must be able to keep his business
intact, hold his customers, and retain in his employment
all the labor and the capital that he has.
Equality of Size of Productive
Establishments not Necessary. - Size
is, as we shall see, an element of efficiency, and
the great establishment often sells goods for less
than it would cost a small one to make them.
The small manufacturer often finds that he would best
become a mere merchant, buying some of the products
of the great mill and selling them to his customers,
rather than continue making similar goods. In
the general market an approach to equality of size
is usually necessary in order that competitors may
be on even terms. This does not preclude the
survival of many small establishments. The local
retailers have an advantage over great department stores
in the filling of small orders. When one has
to buy what costs a dollar it does not pay to spend
a dime in car-fares, and waste a dollar’s worth
of time in order to secure the thing for ninety cents.
Weariness to customers is here the element that gives
to the small producer his advantage and enables him
to keep that part of the business which comes in the
form of many small orders; but small producers often
have other advantages than those which depend on location.
In a shop which is more like that of a craftsman of
three centuries ago than it is like the great furniture
factory, a cabinetmaker can make a single chair of
a special pattern more cheaply than the great manufacturer
can afford to do it. The great shop requires that
there should be many articles of a kind turned out
by its elaborate machines in order that the owner
should get the benefit of their rapid and unerring
action. There will long be at work hand presses
much like those used by Benjamin Franklin, besides
the complicated automata which do the bulk of our
printing, because for printing a dozen copies of anything
the lever press is the cheaper. There will be
shoemakers who not only mend shoes but occasionally
make them for customers who want other than standard
kinds; and local tailors are sure to survive.
Only in the general market and in the making of standard
goods is size essential to success.
A Considerable Number of Competitors
Assumed. - The most striking phenomenon
of our time is the consolidation of independent establishments
by the forming of what are usually called trusts; and
this and all the approaches to it are precluded by
the static hypothesis. There is a question whether,
after competition has reduced the establishments in
one subgroup to a half dozen or less, they would not,
even without forming a trust, act as a quasi-monopoly.
This question we have at the proper point fully to
discuss, but here it is necessary to assume that nothing
which creates even a quasi-monopoly exists. We
shall find that competition usually would, in fact,
survive and be extremely effective among as few as
five or six competitors, till they formed some sort
of union with each other. To avoid all uncertainty
we assume that in the static state in which values,
wages, and interest are natural and in which each subgroup
has its perfectly normal share of labor and capital,
there are competitors enough in each occupation to
preclude all question as to the continuance of an
active rivalry.
Static Values and Prices. - The
equilibrium referred to requires that all values should
stand at their static levels, which means that the
prices of goods should be the “cost prices”
of the older economists. The entrepreneur
should make no net profit on the goods he is producing.
The wages of labor must be productivity wages, since
each man must get the amount of wealth that he brings
into existence. Interest on capital needs, in
like manner, to be productivity interest, and each
unit of capital must get the amount it creates.
Moreover, the prices of goods, as expressed in money,
must be accurate representations of the comparative
values of goods. All these features mark the
static state; but the most obvious mark of distinction
is the absence of movement from group to group.
We shall see that values are ultimately measured in
marginal labor, and as the value of money is measured
in the same way, it follows that the price of each
article, as expressed in money, is in a static state
a correct expression of the comparative amount of
labor that will make it. And the entire relation
of commodities to each other and to labor can be expressed
by the medium of currency. If a unit of labor
produces gold enough to make an eagle, and if any
commodity sells for ten dollars, it will be safe to
infer that it is also produced by one unit of labor.
If one commodity sells for ten dollars and another
for five dollars, the former is the product of twice
as many units of marginal labor as is the latter.
This remains true only while currency continues to
be in its normal state and all other static adjustments
continue complete.
Influences that disturb the Static
Equilibrium. - It might seem that the influences that disturb such a static
equilibrium are too numerous to be described; and yet these changes may be
classed under five general types: -
1. Growth of Population. - The
supply of labor is increasing, and this fact of itself
calls for continual readjustment of the group system.
2. Increase of Capital. - The
amount of capital is increasing, and this change also
disturbs the static equilibrium and calls for a rearrangement.
As far as wages and interest are concerned, the effect
of this latter change is the opposite of that which
follows an increase in the amount of labor. When
people become more numerous, other things remaining
equal, their individual earning capacity becomes smaller.
The increase of capital reduces the earning power of
each unit of the supply of it and depresses the rate
of interest; but it raises the rate of wages, for
it causes labor itself to act more efficiently.
It is to be noted, indeed, that when
new laborers enter society they become consumers as
well as producers, and this affects the utility and
the value of goods. When more people use a given
amount of consumers’ wealth, values, measured
in ultimate units of utility or disutility, rise.
An increase of capital does not directly neutralize
this effect, since it does not change the number of
consumers; but it multiplies commodities and brings
down their utilities and their values. The rise
of “subjective” values which follows an
influx of laborers is an indication of diminished
wealth per capita, and the reduction of values which
follows an influx of capital is a sign of increased
wealth per capita.
3. Changes of Method. - Changes
take place in the methods of production. New
processes are devised, improved machines are invented,
cheap motive powers are utilized, and cheap and available
raw materials are discovered, and these changes continually
disturb the static state. There are certain to
be improvements on the older methods of production,
for a law of the survival of the fittest insures this.
Under competition the process that,
with a given amount of labor and capital, turns out
a larger product inevitably displaces one that turns
out less. The employer who is using the better
method undersells those who use inferior ones, and
forces them either to improve their own methods or
to go out of business. Working humanity as a whole
is therefore making a constant gain in producing power,
as man’s appliances equip him more and more
effectively for his conflict with nature and enable
him to subjugate it more rapidly and thoroughly.
It would seem that they ought to have only good effects
on wages, and in the long run they invariably do have
such effects. In the absence of improvements
there would be little hope for the future of wage
earners. The immediate effects of improvements
upon individual workers, as we shall see, are not
always unqualifiedly good, but the essential effect
is the general and permanent one, and the character
of this has been attested by past experience too fully
to be in doubt. In improvements in production
lies the hope of laboring humanity. Nearly the
whole earning power of the labor of the present day
is the result of improvements that have taken place
in the past, though these gains have not been secured
without causing local and temporary hardships.
If in the future the wages of labor are doubled or
quadrupled, as the result of a series of improvements
beginning now and extending to a remote period, this
progress cannot be secured for nothing. The costs
will be less than those attending improvements of
the past, but they will be real. The most important
fact is that they tend to become fewer and smaller
and that the gains immeasurably exceed them.
4. Changes in Organization. - There
are changes in the mode of organizing the establishments
in which commodities are produced, and so far as these
occur under a regime of active competition, they also
are improvements and give added power of production.
The mills and shops become larger and relatively fewer.
There is a great centralizing movement going on, since
the large shop undersells and suppresses the smaller
one, and combinations unite many great shops under
one management. The effect of this, when it takes
place in a perfectly normal way, is akin to that of
improvements of method. It benefits society as
a whole somewhat at the cost of individual members
of the body, and it causes wages to rise by adding
continually to the wealth-creating power of the men
who earn them. We shall see that when consolidations
repress competition their effect is far from being
thus wholly beneficial, and that not only are particular
persons injured by them, but the community as a whole
has a serious bill of charges to bring against them.
The securing of the gains that come by consolidation
without such evils is an end the realization of which
will tax the statesmanship of the future.
5. Changes in Consumers’
Wants. - The wants of consumers are changing.
They are growing more numerous as well as more refined
and intellectual. This expansion of desires follows
the general increase of productive power, since every
one already wants some things that he cannot procure,
and all society has a fringe of ungratified wants just
beyond the limit of actual gratification. Even
if all these wants that are now near the point of
actual satisfaction were to be satisfied, the desires
would at once project themselves farther. The
mere increase in earning power without any special
education enlarges the want scale, but intellectual
and moral growth cooeperates with it in that direction
and calls latent wants into an active state. More
and more eagerly do men seek things for which the
desire was formerly dormant. Changes of this
kind affect values, cause labor and capital to move
from group to group, and thus cause society as a whole
to produce less of some things and more of others.
They sometimes cause wholly new groups to appear,
and draw workers and equipment from the old ones.
Advantage of Diversity of Wants. - One
very marked effect of the diversification of wants
is to increase the aggregate utility of a mass of
commodity produced with a given expenditure of labor.
Measure the whole wealth available for consumption
on the basis of the labor that it takes to create
it, and it will appear that it has more utility and
is worth more to society in consequence of this evolution
that is going on in the nature of the individual consumer.
A given amount of labor benefits most the men whose
wants are of the most varied character. If A,
B, and C are three commodities, and if
their several utilities decline, as successive units
of them are given to a consumer, along the curves
descending from the letters A, B, and
C of the diagram, it is clear that the man whose
consumption is confined to the commodity A gets less
benefit from three units of wealth than does the man
who consumes A, B, and C.
The utility of the first unit of A is measured
by the vertical line from A to the line DE,
that of the second by the line from A’
to DE, and that of the third by the line from
A’’ to DE. The utility
of the first unit of B is measured by the distance
from B to the line DE and exceeds that
of the second unit of A by the difference between
the lengths of those lines. In like manner the
utility of C exceeds that of the third unit
of A by the difference between the length of
the line descending from C and that of the one descending
from A’’. The declining utility
of the income of the man who satisfies three wants
is represented by the slowly descending curve ABC,
while the diminishing utility of the income of the
man who satisfies only one want declines along the
sharply descending curve A, A’,
A’’.
Changes in Static Standards. - The
grand resultant of all the changes that are going
on in the more highly civilized countries is a continual
rise, not only in actual wages but in the theoretical
standard of wages. The static or “natural”
rate of pay for labor to-day is higher than it was
fifty years ago and lower than it will naturally be
fifty years hence. Removing all disturbing influences
and letting society settle to-day into a perfectly
static condition would reveal the theoretical standard
of present wages. Doing the same thing after
a lapse of fifty years would show what would then be
the natural or standard rate; and this would be higher
than the present one. Not only would the actual
pay of labor have risen, but the standard to which
it tends to conform would have become higher after
every interval. The actual rate of wages at any
one time varies from the standard; but as both rise
from decade to decade, the actual rate hovers all
the while within a certain distance of the standard
one.
Effects on Values. - In
the same way the values of goods measured in labor
will in general be declining values. At no one
time will actual market prices accurately express
the amounts of marginal labor that are required for
producing different articles, but they will approximately
express this. Articles will sell in the market
for about enough to pay for the labor that, when used
as marginal labor, suffices to produce them; and as
this amount of labor put into a given article grows
less and less, the prices of the goods will actually
pay for fewer and fewer days’ labor.
The standard price of anything will
be the amount of money that is needed to pay for the
labor of making it, provided always that we are careful
to use only empty-handed labor in applying the test
and that we put that labor in the marginal position,
as described in Chapters IV and V, and so disentangle
the product that is attributable to it from that which
is imputable to capital. If wages, as paid in
money, remain stationary, normal prices will decline
and actual prices will hover about them in their downward
course, so that goods will actually buy smaller and
smaller amounts of labor, or, what is the same thing,
labor will secure as its pay more and more goods.
In connection with the cost in labor
of different articles it is to be remembered that
in agriculture the effect of improvements of method
may not always suffice to counteract the working
of the so-called law of diminishing returns, which
insures, with agricultural science in a given state
of advancement, smaller products per capita when
there are more men on a given area. That
this influence should preponderate over that of
improved processes requires that population should
increase with a degree of rapidity which may or may
not be maintained.