THE LIMITS OF AN ECONOMIC SOCIETY
When we try to establish a standard
to which wages generally tend to conform, the question
arises how much of the earth we have in view.
Is there a rate at which the pay of labor in Europe,
Asia, Africa, Australia, and America tends to settle
and remain? Is there a common rate of interest
that is normal in all these grand divisions, and are
there also general standards of value for goods which
govern their prices in all the markets of the world?
If there are no such standards having universal validity,
are there any that are valid within single geographical
divisions? On what principle can we divide the
earth into sections for economic purposes? These
are some of the questions which must be answered if
a theory of distribution is to have any definiteness
of meaning, and they arise whenever we try to establish
a static standard of any kind. If we talk about
natural wages, we must know in how much of the world
they are natural. The questions become even more
urgent when we try to solve dynamic problems.
We shall have to determine the effects of an influx
of labor into the economic society we are studying;
but does this mean an increase of population in the
world as a whole? Does an influx of capital have
a similar comprehensive meaning, and does an improvement
in the method of producing some commodity mean a change
in the mode of making it in every part of the world
where it is produced at all? We need to know
how extensive the society is whose activities we are
examining.
Characteristics of an Economic
Society. - We have said that there are
natural rates of wages, etc., within some area,
which we have regarded as containing an economic society,
and we have treated this social organism much as though
it were as isolated and self-contained as would be
an inaccessible island with its population. It
has one general market where values are fixed.
A farmer within the area covered by our studies produces
wheat for the whole society, and in one way or another,
every person within the area is a bidder for it.
A shoemaker makes shoes and a weaver makes cloth to
offer to everybody. Each part of the organism
ministers to the whole and is ministered to by the
whole. Competition is ideally free and in a sense
is universal. The general system of groups made
up of the A’s, the B’s, the C’s,
and the H’s of our table illustrates the manner
in which this complete and self-contained society
is organized. In the static state there is one
standard of wages for all these groups and their subdivisions
and one equally general standard of interest.
The price of a commodity, barring some allowance for
cost of carrying it, is uniform everywhere. A
reduced price for A’’’M in
any part of the area where this society dwells would
set men bidding for it from every quarter of that area
and would thus bring the local prices to uniformity.
So a high rate of pay for labor in one part would
at once lure men from every other part and reduce
the high pay to the standard generally prevailing.
The picture is that of a social body having a large
geographical extension and yet intensely sensitive
at every point to economic influences. Prices,
wages, and interest everywhere respond at once to an
influence that originates in any part of the extended
area. In technical terms this means that there
is perfect mobility of labor and capital within the
group system represented by the table, and that this
involves equally perfect mobility as between parts
of the area that the groups inhabit. Men move
from one section of the country to another in response
to an economic inducement as readily as they do from
the group A to the group B.
Barriers which divide the World
into Economic Sections. - Now it is clear
that in the actual world changing one’s place
of abode is difficult, and even sending capital from
place to place is somewhat so. Inequalities of
earning power are not leveled out by a quick migration
of laborers from China to Europe or to America.
In their methods of production the different regions
are not brought to a uniformity, for there is machine
labor here and hand labor there; and it is vain to
expect that machines will quickly become universal
and that the practical arts in America, Africa, and
Asia will be rendered uniform by such a quick adoption
of the most efficient processes as economic law, in
the absence of friction, requires.
Boundaries of the Society which
is here Studied. - If we take the world
as a whole into the circle covered by our studies,
we find that labor, compared with other economic elements,
decidedly lacks fluidity and does not easily move.
So far from being like water, which flows readily
and finds its level quickly, it is more like tar or
other viscous stuff, which flows slowly and is long
in leveling out local irregularities in its surface.
In the world as a whole there are regions crowded
with people and other regions nearly unpeopled, and
long will it be before some of these differences will
be much reduced. Many centuries, indeed, must
pass before they are entirely removed. If, however,
we take the most active part of the world, - western
Europe, most of North America, Japan, and the more
fully settled parts of Australia, - labor
will show a degree of mobility that makes it more
like the water of the illustration, and capital within
this active center of industrial operations will be
more fluid still. Prices here tend toward certain
general standards, and processes of production and
methods of organizing the forces which do the producing
work tend strongly toward uniformity. The best
processes and the best forms of organization tend
generally to survive. There are imperative reasons
for studying the economy of this highly civilized region,
the center of the economic activities of the world,
apart from that of the more undeveloped regions.
The Need of a Rule by which a Part
of the World may be Treated as an Economic Society. - This
involves finding a way by which we can treat a limited
part of the world much as though it were, for our purposes,
the whole of it. In essential ways the economic
center that we have described does act somewhat as
if it were an organism complete in itself. We
must draw a boundary line about the area of active
movement, of lively interchanges, and of general sensitiveness
to economic influences, thus separating it from the
broader zone of sluggish movement of capital and population,
of slow response to economic stimuli, and of generally
backward conditions.
Freedom of Movement as a Test. - In
Europe, America, and the other advanced regions goods
are carried from place to place so easily and quickly
that there is a tendency toward uniform prices; and
such local differences of price as exist in the case
of any commodity do not much exceed the cost of getting
it carried from one place to another, though in the
cost of moving it there must often be reckoned the
toll which a government takes at the customhouse.
Capital moves freely, and there is a certain approach
to a general level of interest, though here also local
differences of course survive. The obstacle to
the moving of capital from one place to another, if
the owner does not go with it, is occasioned mainly
by the risk it encounters and by a virtual bill for
insurance. With allowance for this cost, rates
of interest in the region we have described tend toward
a general level. Though labor migrates more slowly
than capital, it moves far more rapidly within the
economic center than in the outer zones. Processes
of production are not brought to a complete uniformity
within the center, but they tend powerfully toward
it; for while obstructions exist, they surely and
not always slowly yield. With due regard for
such differences of method as those existing between
the European ways of making products and the American
ways, we may say that the tendency toward the general
survival of the best methods is too strong to allow
any important differences to be permanent. Everywhere,
in short, within the central area there is a strong
tendency to conform to economic standards in the matter
of prices, wages, interest, industrial processes,
and forms of economic organization. The standards
are what we have defined as the static ones. If
we should stop progress and all disturbing influences
and wait long enough, we should see values, wages,
interest, etc., take a static level throughout
the vast area. This, however, would require that
migrations should go on till all inducement to move
from place to place should have ceased to exist.
Population would then have distributed itself over
the land in the most advantageous way, and no body
of people would be better off than any other by reason
of the location of their abode. A long period
would be needed to bring about this adjustment even
within the circumscribed area where influences that
make for change are very active and where obstacles
are far smaller than they are in the uncivilized regions.
Essential Density of Population. - A
perfectly static state requires, not a perfectly equal
distribution of population, but such a distribution
that there is no reason for further migrating.
The power of the soil to feed its inhabitants varies
with its fertility. Where the land is highly
productive a dense population may live easily; whereas
on a sterile soil even a sparse population may find
natural resources too meager, and men may move to
places which are more thickly peopled and yet may
gain by the change. Moreover, such occupations
as manufacturing and commerce require, of course, a
far larger population on a given area than does any
form of agriculture. Some regions are so undesirable
as dwelling places that it takes an exceptional economic
reward to induce men to live there. The static
state is one in which, all these things being considered,
there is no reason for changing the place of one’s
abode. This implies more nearly equal density
per unit of natural resources than equal density per
unit of mere area. Inequality of advantage due
to location is what is leveled out, and doing this
does not require nor permit that population should
everywhere be equally dense per square mile or per
acre.
Effect of Differences of Occupation. - Regions
given over to agriculture naturally sustain more people
than those devoted to grazing, and those which are
devoted to manufacturing sustain more than either.
In countries in which, as in Great Britain, manufacturing
is so disproportionately developed that products must
be largely exported, while food must be largely imported,
given areas sustain more inhabitants than they do
in any agricultural or grazing region and more than
they do in any region where grazing and tillage, on
the one hand, and manufacturing, on the other, are
well balanced. In mills and shops auxiliary capital
so abounds as to take the place of the abundant land
that is available in the other cases for making labor
fruitful, and in villages and cities labor does not
overtax the resources of the soil any more than it
does on farms. It has area enough to live and
to work on and tools and materials enough to work
with. In a generally crowded country, the resort
to commerce and manufacturing relieves the pressure
on the land, cities abound, and an abundance of capital
averts the danger of a disastrous overcrowding.
An approximately Static Distribution
of Population. - The apportionment of
population among the different sections of a country
may be nearly normal, while migration may still go
on from that country as a whole to remote parts of
the general area which we include in our present study.
There may be small reason for moving from one part
of Germany to another and large reason for going from
Germany to America. This larger movement occupies
a long time, while certain other adjustments may be
made more quickly. Within Germany and within
the United States labor may be well apportioned among
the different occupations. There may be in each
country about the right comparative numbers of cotton
spinners, iron workers, gardeners, wheat raisers,
etc.; or in other words, the distribution of labor
among the industrial groups may be approximately normal
both within the one country and within the other.
It may further be true that the division of occupations
between the two countries in their entirety is about
what, in the conditions now prevailing, economic law
calls for. There are certain industries which
now have their habitats in Germany and certain others
that have their habitats in the United States, and
this arrangement is partly due to the comparative
density of the two populations. Because there
are so many persons per square mile of land in Germany
there is there a certain preponderance of manufacturing,
and there are in America less manufacturing and relatively
more agriculture. In that remote time when the
relative density of the two populations shall become
static, America will have reason to increase the comparative
amount of the manufacturing and thus put herself in
this particular more nearly on a plane with Germany.
This occupation has its normal abode in regions of
comparatively dense population, and a gain in comparative
density means an increase in the amount of productive
energy devoted to it. The place for the mill is
where the land is crowded, and the better place for
the work of tillage is where it is not so.
How an Unnatural Distribution of
Population may be Treated. - So long
as the slow movement of population from country to
country remains incomplete, the ultimate division
of occupations between the countries can never be
completely static. It is therefore with a division
that is only approximately static that we have first
to deal, and this is realized when in view of the
comparative density of population in the different
regions which now exists occupations are naturally
apportioned.
The base line AD of this figure
stands for the part of the world in which economic
law works rapidly and encounters comparatively few
obstructions; and the extension of the line represents
the lands outside of this region in which the laws
are sluggish in their action. It is as though
this base line were a section of a vast surface including
both civilized and primitive states. AB represents
the smallest population per unit of land of a given
quality within the central area, and DC represents
the largest, while the ascending line BC shows
the gradations of essential density in the peopling
of different parts of it. At the point A the
pressure of the population on the resources of the
soil is least, while at the point D it is at
its greatest. At the point A a man can
get much out of the soil as the return for his own
bare labor, while at D he can get comparatively
little; and at intervening points on the base a man
gets more than he does at D and less than he
does at A. His gains measured in bushels
of wheat, etc., vary inversely as the density
of the population and so decrease from the left of
the figure toward the right till the point D
is reached. The occupations of the different
localities are determined by these facts.
How Occupations vary with Differences
of Land Crowding. - Crowding the arable
land causes labor to flow naturally to manufacturing
occupations, since in these it is not so greatly handicapped
in comparison with the labor of more sparsely peopled
regions. In a cotton mill in Manchester a man
may contribute as many yards per day toward the product
of the mill as he would in a mill in Fall River; but
on an English farm one man’s labor does not create
as much produce as it does on an American farm.
The large amount of available land per man in America
has a great effect on the amount that a man can produce
by tilling it, but it has very little effect on the
amount of the cotton goods that his presence and labor
in the mill insure. In raising crops, therefore,
the Englishman is at a more serious disadvantage in
comparison with the American. The fact is expressed
in a practical way by saying that the English labor
is cheaper and is therefore more available for making
things that are exported to the distant markets of
the world than is labor of the same kind in America;
but the reason for this cheapness is primarily the
land crowding, which reduces the productive power
of a final unit of labor in the former country.
Because the man cannot get for himself many bushels
of wheat per annum by working on land he can afford
to work in a mill at a rate corresponding with the
value of the produce he could secure as a cultivator.
General Differences between the
Condition of Densely Peopled Regions and that of Sparsely
Peopled Ones. - In a very general way
it may be said that the comparative amount of manufacturing
should naturally vary directly with density of population,
and that the comparative amount of agriculture should
vary inversely to it. In computing density due
regard must, as has been indicated, be paid to the
quality of the land as well as the area, since a number
of inhabitants which would unduly congest a sterile
agricultural region can be well maintained on a fertile
one. In the accompanying figure the line AD
inclosed by the vertical lines represents the part
of the earth which we have called central, and the
left side of it is the part of this area which has
the sparsest population, while the right side is that
which has the densest. The rising line BC
represents the varying density of the population in
different parts of the broad area we regard as general
economic society, the dotted line EF may be
taken as expressing the increase in the part of the
labor and capital of the country devoted to manufacturing
as population becomes denser, AE measures the
proportionate number of persons engaged in manufacturing
in the region of sparsest population, and DF
measures the comparative number in the region most
densely peopled.
AG and DH represent
the numbers engaged in agriculture in the two regions,
and the descent of the line GH represents the
predominance of agriculture in the sparsely populated
part and the subordination of it in the part that
is densely populated. If we assume that capital
in the different types of employment varies as does
labor, the descent of this line toward the right means
a decline in the fraction of the whole force of labor
and of the whole fund of capital devoted to cultivating
the soil; while the upward trend of EF means
the enlarging proportion of labor and capital devoted
to manufacturing as we pass from a region of sparse
population to regions more and more crowded.
The wavy character of the two dotted lines is designed
to express the fact that local conditions other than
mere density of population favor the one type of occupation
rather than the other; and moreover, nothing in the
figure is intended to mean that the increase in manufacturing
and the comparative decrease in tillage from the left
of the diagram to the right are in any exact numerical
proportion to the increase in the density of population.
The figure as a whole rudely represents the fact that
an approximation to the static distribution of population
insures an approximation to a static apportionment
of occupations within the described area and indicates
the general nature of that apportionment.
How Cost of Production and Cost
of Acquisition are Equalized. - The costs
of moving goods from place to place - including
in these costs commercial charges and duties imposed
by governments - are the cause of most of
the manufacturing that is done in the region represented
by the left side of the diagram, except the production
of such articles for immediate or local consumption
as are necessarily made at or near the places where
they are used. Tailoring, blacksmithing, carpentering,
general repairing, etc., would always be done
in that region, but many kinds of staple goods capable
of being transported would, in the absence of duties
on imports, be made chiefly in the region of dense
population and cheap labor.
The general rule for determining whether a branch of
manufacturing can survive in the area of abundant land and well-paid labor is as
follows: it can do so if the cost of making the article which this branch
of business is devoted to producing is as low as the cost of acquiring it by
exchange. The cost may in both cases be reduced to bare labor and the rule
will then stand thus: if ten days labor will make the article and if nine
will make something that can be exchanged for it - i.e.
if all the costs of the exchange can be covered and
the thing can be brought from abroad for a total expenditure
of nine days’ labor instead of ten - the
manufacturing of that article will not survive.
In a region of abundant land and well-paid labor it
is chiefly the tolls which governments exact which
make it as costly an operation to get the manufactured
products by producing other things to barter for them
as it is to make them directly. Density of population,
overworking of land, meagerness of returns to agricultural
labor - these are the conditions that primarily
fix the habitat of most kinds of manufacturing.
In the case of particular products these influences
may be overcome by the presence in limited parts of
the sparsely settled area of exceptional natural advantages
for production. Natural gas, special ores, particular
kinds of lumber, etc., may draw some branches
of manufacturing to the region of fertile land and
high wages; but as the comparison which we are making
is the most general one which it is possible to make
we are safe in our assertion that, in the main, manufacturing
processes tend, in the absence of exceptional influences,
to concentrate themselves in the region of dense population
and of meager earning power of labor.
The Approximate Static Adjustment
of Prices. - In the main, and with tariffs
as they are, the price of raw products is somewhat
lower at the left of the figure, while that of highly
wrought merchandise is markedly lower at the right
of it; and with the comparative density of population
as it is and with no change of commercial policy on
the part of governments, this condition may be expected
to continue. It is an approximately static adjustment
of prices. Purchasing manufactured goods in Europe
will long be profitable if they can be passed duty
free through the customhouse, while food will be somewhat
cheaper in America.
Static Wages and Interest. - As
has been said, the wages of labor are comparatively
low at the right and high at the left of the figure,
while interest varies in the two regions in the same
way. It is lower in the crowded area. This
is not because of the presence of many men, for this
influence alone would tend to sustain the productive
power of capital and the consequent rate of interest,
and in fact the interest on capital in Europe would
be lower than it is if the population there were sparser.
The rate which prevails is fixed by the productive
power of a very large fund of artificial capital utilized
by a large population meagerly supplied with land.
This last item is decisive in the case and is a primary
cause of low interest. The full statement of
these facts, made in graphic form, shows an ascending
line of density of population, as we proceed from
left to right, an ascending line of price for raw
produce, a descending line of price for highly wrought
merchandise, and descending lines for wages and interest.
All these lines represent the facts in a broadly general
way. They deal with averages and not with particular
rates. The labor whose earning power descends
along the line numbered 5 is of many kinds, and the
produce of which the average values vary along the
lines numbered 2 and 4 is of many varieties.
The rate of ascent or descent of the lines has no
especial quantitative significance, and it is therefore
not implied in the figure that wages decline more
rapidly than the other factors. Moreover, it
is such large areas as those of England, Germany, France,
or the Mississippi Valley, including both cities and
rural lands, that we have in mind when we speak of
the density of population as ascending along the line
numbered 1. Anywhere we expect to find cities
containing more persons to the acre than rural districts.
The purpose of the figure is to enable us to take
in at a glance five different adjustments that in
the main are to be regarded as approximately static
within the great region described as the economic center
of the world.
Slow Change of the Foregoing Adjustments. - The
line which represents the comparative density of population
is of course slowly changing position as migration
goes on from the older centers of population to more
newly occupied regions. If the present distribution
of population be represented by the line numbered
1, the distribution a hundred years hence may be represented
by the dotted line numbered 2, and that which will
exist after five hundred years shall have passed may
be represented by the dotted line numbered 3.
Even within the economic center the comparative density
of population in different divisions is therefore
not to be treated as strictly permanent, and it is
not to be treated as in any sense permanent when we
are forecasting effects that will be realized several
centuries hence. For a problem involving a score
or two of years the general conditions we have described
may be treated as, in the main, abiding.
This, however, is only one reason for
this limitation of the scope of our immediate
study. A serious fact is that, if we include
the entire world, we cannot establish, in the way we
have proposed, the natural standards toward which
values, wages, and interest are tending.
It will be recalled that in the static division
of this treatise we have attained a “natural”
standard of wages by assuming that all dynamic changes
were to cease and that labor and capital were to move
to and fro in the system of industrial groups till
each of these agents produced as much in one subgroup
as in another. A computation of this kind
might, within a limited area, be made periodically,
say once in ten years, and if this were done it
would give a series of static standards of wages.
Now these standards become higher as time advances.
The static rate of pay for labor is, as a rule,
higher at any one date than was the standard for
a date ten years earlier, and lower than will
be that for a date ten years later. The normal
rate of pay about which actual wages fluctuate
is a rising one.
Now, if we introduce in imagination
an absolutely static state for the world at large,
we shall have to assume that growth of the general
population and increase of the aggregate capital
both cease, and that inventions and new cooerdinations
are no longer made. We must then wait long enough
to allow static distribution of industries to be made
over the whole world and to let each industry find
its absolute habitat. This would involve
causing methods of producing any commodity to
be unified the world over. Hand labor in
the Orient would have to give way to machine production,
as it has done in Western lands. For a strictly
static adjustment indeed even the density of population
in the different sections would have to be brought
to a virtual equality. While this nearly
interminable process was going on, it would be
needful that such dynamic changes as inventions
and discoveries bring in their train should be absolutely
precluded. Stop making new kinds of machinery
and wait for centuries to allow a static adjustment
to be made over the whole earth - such
would be the order.
Now, such a test as this would show
falling wages in the more favored parts of the
earth, whereas the facts show rising wages.
The influx of population from the East, unrelieved
by a corresponding influx of new capital and by
more fruitful methods of production, would cause
the earnings of an American laborer to fall, and
we should, on the basis of such a test, conclude
that his wages in the long run are destined to
become lower in consequence of the movement of the
vast populations that now congest great Asiatic
countries. We should have vitiated the problem
by holding the growth of capital and the progress
of invention in abeyance. This may be done
within a limited area without giving a false result,
because there adjustments are more rapid, and waiting
for them does not involve the long-continued paralysis
of the powers that make for greater wealth for
laboring humanity. Apply the test of the
static state to the economic center, and it will
give a generally true result; but it will give a false
one if it be applied to the world as a whole.
The merely static adjustment of the world would
take more centuries than we care to reckon, and
no truth that we are seeking is revealed by assuming
that for such a period the forces of progress
are brought to a standstill.