FURTHER INFLUENCES WHICH REDUCE THE
HARDSHIPS ENTAILED BY DYNAMIC CHANGES
In the absence of an unusually great
increase in the consumption of an article the improvement
which reduces the cost of it tends to displace labor.
The first thing that will occur to any one who looks
for influences which mitigate this evil is the fact
that economical changes are going on at nearly all
points in the system, and that this cancels out most
of the displacing influence. If something sends
men from the group A to groups B and
C, while something else sends them from the
group B to groups A and C, and
still another influence impels men from C to
A and B, there is likely to be very
little actual moving. A question will in such
a case arise as to whether the three movements may
not expel labor from all the groups and remand them
to a state of idleness. History is clear in the
answer it gives to this question; such a result has
not occurred, and at the end of a century of brilliant
mechanical progress the amount of enforced idleness
is not greater than it was at the outset. It remains
to show that economic law precludes a universal displacement
and insures laborers for all time against being at
the mercy of an industrial system which has nowhere
any need of their services. Productive devices
widely introduced mean great and general gains and
comparatively little cost. They mean what on their
face they ought to mean, more comforts and less toil
for everybody. Before studying this influence - the
reciprocal action of improvements scattered through
the general economic system - we have to
determine the action of one or two other influences
which also lessen the disturbances which progress
causes.
One can see that the quick adoption
of an economical device in every shop of a subgroup,
at a time when all other industries are in a stationary
state, would usually expel some labor from that one.
If consumers should, on a large scale, substitute
the product of this subgroup for that of others, it
might save the situation; but the general fact is
that the consumption of the cheapened product must
increase in a ratio that is greater than the ratio
representing the saving of labor used in making it,
in order to prevent displacement of labor. If
we get on with two thirds of the labor which the making
of the commodity out of raw materials formerly required,
we do not save two thirds of the total expense of
making the finished article; and yet to retain all
the labor that is now in the business we must sell
one and a half times the former number of the goods
produced.
Counteracting Influences. - The
importance of a gradual introduction of an improvement
rather than a rapid one lies in the fact that it permits
these influences to do their work and often to render
the actual moving of laborers even from their subgroup
unnecessary. Time is the salvation of the laborer
menaced by an impending displacement from his field.
When we see what is the grand resultant of all the
dynamic influences we are studying, we shall see how
this neutralizing and canceling of the labor-expelling
force takes place. But for them one isolated
change would tend to expel labor from its subgroup
and would nearly always send it away from the point
within an establishment where the new device is introduced.
It usually attracts labor to this establishment and
away from the inefficient or marginal ones. A
gradual adoption of the improvement allows time not
only for a general increase in the size and the wealth
of the community, but for other influences which act
more quickly and in practice make it nearly always
unnecessary to reduce the total amount of labor in
an industry which produces an article in permanent
demand. Statistics may be confidently appealed
to in support of this general statement.
The Dynamic Law of Price and its
Effects. - We briefly noted in passing
that the price of a product the making of which is
subject to repeated improvements naturally tends toward
the cost of it in the establishment having the latest
method and the greatest facilities for production.
The natural price at any time is the cost of that part
of the supply which is created at the greatest advantage,
and not the cost of the part produced at the greatest
disadvantage, as an old formula expressed it.
It is the mill that makes the goods most cheaply which
is enlarging its product and bringing the price down
toward its level of cost; as soon as other establishments
get possession of the improvement they help forward
the process, and as they get still better appliances
they help in carrying the price to still newer and
lower standards.
The Cause of the Coincidence of
Maximum Cost and Price. - At any one
moment, it is true, there are ill-located, ill-equipped,
or ill-managed mills that are making nothing and are
likely soon to be abandoned. They are the marginal
mills we have spoken of, and the goods that they make
cost all that purchasers will give for them. This
insures a coincidence of the price of the goods with
the cost of making them in such a mill, but this is
merely an incident in the process of eliminating the
inefficient establishments from the field. In
the mill which happens at this date to be the one about
to be crowded out the cost of the goods equals the
selling price of them and will exceed it as soon as
the price goes to a lower point. This cost happens
transiently to coincide with the price, but does not
regulate it. It is the outlay that the
best mill incurs that does that, since it sets the
standard toward which the price is made to tend.
The figure represents a subgroup in
which five producers, a, b, c,
d, and e, are operating. Later,
a new establishment f, is introduced.
The upper dark line represents the price of a
unit of the product, and the lower dark line the
cost of making a unit in the establishment which
is for the time the most efficient.
The dotted lines represent the respective
costs of production in the different mills, ranging
from a, the most efficient, to e, which can barely hold its own.
What the figure represents as happening is as follows: -
b first makes an improvement
which lowers his cost of production, as shown
by the descending dotted line. This enables
him to increase his output, and so has its effect on
the price, which descends. Now, producer e
was already selling goods at cost, but he is not
at once driven out of the business. Instead,
even though he cannot earn full interest on the
original cost of his fixed establishment, he will
continue to run as long as he can make his plant earn
anything at all. The result is a virtual reduction
of the capitalized value of the plant (the interest
on which is an item of cost), and this is what
is represented by the descent of the dotted line
which represents es cost of production. The situation is now
represented by the series of points, - b’, a’,
c’, etc., representing at their
second stage the differing levels of cost in the
case of different producers.
The next thing that happens is an improvement
made by a, causing his cost of production
to fall below that of b. The resulting
fall in price now finally drives e out of business;
he can no longer earn anything at all on his fixed
plant. We may assume that producers a,
b, and c, who have been making profits,
have enlarged their productive capacity enough
to supply the market fully without e’s
contribution. d is now in the same position
in which e was at the preceding stage, - earning
nothing on his fixed establishment and barely
induced to remain in the business.
The next occurrence represented is the
opening of a new, large, and very efficient mill
by f. The effect is like that of improvements,
but more violent. The fall in price drives
both d and c out of business. b
is now on the margin, but saves himself from loss
by a second improvement, which makes him again
the most efficient producer. And so the process
goes on ad infinitum.
This figure illustrates the fact that,
while at any time the price of a good roughly
equals the cost of it to the least efficient producers,
still this cost does not govern the price.
The ruling factor is the cost in the most efficient
mill, toward which the price tends; and all that
the cost in the least efficient mill determines
is how long that mill shall continue running.
In order that the claim here made - that
price equals cost in the establishment which is
about to be crowded out of the field - may
hold good it is necessary to define terms with some
care. In a typical case an employer who is destined
soon to close out his business has, perhaps, an
antiquated mill, which itself pays nothing, but
enables its owner to use circulating capital and
labor in a way that affords interest on that capital
and wages for the labor. No interest on the cost
of the antiquated mill is chargeable to the business
unless the site and the building can be sold for
a new purpose. If they have completely lost
all productive power, they are not, as we use
terms, capital goods at all; and in that case
the only interest which the entrepreneur should
reckon as a cost is that which accrues on other
capital used in connection with the worthless
mill. If the site and the building have some
value for another purpose, and if the machinery
has some value as junk, then whatever the owner can
get by disposing of the plant constitutes a sum
the interest on which constitutes a cost of producing
goods in this mill. It is a sum which the
plant owner foregoes as long as he refrains from
selling the plant. He can afford to use it in
production as long as the price of the product
covers the cost as thus defined, but must stop
when it ceases to do so.
The Importance of Delay in the
Closing of Marginal Establishments. - Now,
this process looks as if, by the closing of mills
that are distanced in the race of improvement, labor
must be forced out of the subgroup. So it would
be if the reducing of the price to its new static
level were an instantaneous operation and the inferior
mills were, in the same instantaneous fashion, compelled
to close their doors. These, however, are gradual
operations, and before they can possibly produce their
full effects, influences will have been set working
which will counteract the expelling tendency.
We have cited as such an influence the general growth
of society in numbers, wealth, and consuming power,
making it possible for a group, when an economical
change has taken place, to produce and sell more goods
than before and to keep its accustomed force of labor
in order to do so. There are certain more specific
influences which have a similar effect and render
it as unnecessary as it is useless to attempt to resist
the course of improvement.
Centralization of Business an Effect
of Progress. - From the facts here cited
it appears that conservatism of the kind that resists
all changes condemns an entrepreneur to destruction.
He must keep in a moving procession in order to survive.
As the essential thing which is changing is the price-making
cost of goods, the entrepreneur must see to
it that in his establishment cost declines. While
this does not necessarily mean that every such establishment
needs forever to grow larger, since there are local
conditions in which relatively small shops may be
economical enough to survive, yet those which cater
to the general market and directly encounter the competition
of the great producing establishments must, as a general
rule, have the advantages of great size in their favor,
or sooner or later be crowded out of the field.
Many of the smaller ones fall by the wayside, and the
business they have done passes to their already large
rivals. Wherein the advantages of the great shop
lie and how one that is of less than a maximum size
may survive in spite of them, are points for later
consideration.
How Displaced Labor is Replaced. - When
men are actually forced to leave an industry, - say
the subgroup A’, - they find
themselves, in the search for employment, in the same
position as a body of newly arrived immigrants in
quest of work. Men of either class must offer
themselves at a rate that will induce employers to
take them. If much new capital has lately been
created, it is naturally possible for the men to get
employment without having to overcome serious friction
or to reduce their demands in the way of pay.
In the absence of such additions to the capital, they
might possibly have to offer some inducement to employers,
in order to overcome their reluctance to make changes
in their shops. We shall see in due time, however,
that where improvements are well distributed through
the industrial society and have their natural effect,
they tend to increase the general demand for labor
at the original rate of pay.
Effects of a Series of Improvements
confined to One Industry contrasted with those of
Improvements diffused through the Groups. - A
continuous series of radical improvements, all originating
at one point, would tend of themselves to cause a
series of expulsions of labor from that point,
and the mere increase of population and wealth might
not so fully counteract this tendency as to prevent
a positive exodus of labor from the occupation affected.
A merely relative reduction of labor in this occupation
would not cause much hardship, since it would only
mean that other industries were attracting the greater
number of young laborers entering the field and gradually
getting a larger and larger part of the whole working
population. If men actually in A’
can stay there, no one is injured; but too great a
concentration of improvements at this point might drive
some of them away. Such concentration is the
opposite of the general rule. Improvements do
not confine themselves to one point or to a few points,
but originate at very many, and this fact neutralizes
their labor-expelling tendency and might reduce it
practically to nil. If labor could be
made more efficient in every group of the whole system,
the result would be to increase the quantity of every
kind of goods. Making more of one’s own
product is acquiring power to buy more of the products
of others; and enlarging the general output of goods
tends thus to increase the demand for all kinds of
goods as well as the supply. If you make clothes
and I provide food, and we exchange products, but
do not satisfy each other’s wants to the point
of repletion, it is well for both of us that you should
become able to make more clothes and I to furnish
more food. We can then go on with our original
occupations and both live better. In this there
is involved no displacement of labor at all; and neither
would there need to be any disturbance caused by multiplying
in well-adjusted proportions the output of each group
and subgroup in the system of industry. Where
formerly a unit of A’’’ was
exchanged for one of B’’’
or C’’’, there are now two
units of A’’’ given for two
of either B’’’ or C’’’,
and every one has more things to consume than he formerly
had.
Labor attracted toward a Subgroup
as a Result of Improvements which are made Elsewhere. - The
fact that the demand of consumers for different goods
is not uniformly elastic has to be taken into account.
There are two distinct kinds of movements in the group
system, brought about by improvements in method.
Each improvement in and of itself has, as a rule,
a labor-expelling effect, but this effect is partly
neutralized by general growth in consumption and still
more by improvements occurring elsewhere. Labor
that is thrown out of the A group would naturally
go to group B, C, etc.; but if,
as we have just seen, similar influences tend to expel
labor from the B group and the C group,
the labor may, for the most part, stay where it is,
with the result that more of A’’’,
B’’’, and C’’’
is offered to consumers. The increased output of
one group is itself a means of retaining labor in
other groups, even though, thanks to mere methods,
that involves making more of every other kind of commodity.
The Supply of One Kind of Goods
Equivalent to a Demand for Others. - There
should be no difficulty in interpreting, in this connection,
the traditional statement that “the supply of
one kind of goods constitutes a demand for another.”
An increment of A’’’ and
one of B’’’ coming into existence
together supply wants common to their two sets of
producers and both groups can gain by exchanging such
portions of their respective products as they do not
retain for their own use. If A’’’
and B’’’ were the only consumers’
goods used, a part of the excess of each would be
distributed among the members of the group producing
it, and the remainder would be given in exchange for
some of the other kind of goods, also for distribution
among the members of the first-named group. This
is what actually happens when a multitude of articles
for consumption are produced in increasing quantities.
Effect of an Increase of Individual
Incomes on the Character of Goods Consumed. - Such
an increase of the productive power of a group means,
of course, an increase of individual incomes, and it
causes men, as we have seen, to consume better things
rather than more of them. There is a certain
merely quantitative enlargement of every one’s
consumption of goods of a given kind, every one using
more of A’’’ than he used
before; but the greatest change shows itself in the
quality of what he uses. Every man buys and consumes
better articles of the A’’’
kind, as well as of other kinds. His food, his
clothing, etc., are all prepared in a more elaborate
way, and he has more of what we call form utility
which results from the fashioning of things, and relatively
less of the elementary utility which inheres in the
raw material. There is somewhat more of raw material
and very much more form utility in the goods he demands
for personal consumption. This requires that
labor should move upward in the group system, and that
more of it than before should betake itself to those
subgroups where the fashioning of the raw material
is done and where the finishing touches are applied
to goods. The effect of the constant improvement
of all processes of production, therefore, so far
as the effect on labor is concerned, is akin to the
effect of an addition to capital, in that it moves
labor upward in the subgroup series. It puts
more labor into mills and shops which make articles
of comfort and luxury.
The Nature of the Movements actually
caused by Improvements. - This upward
movement cannot go on as smoothly and with as little
disturbance as that which is caused by the increase
of capital. Whenever a greater gain is made at
one point than is made at another, an influence is
set working which, of itself, tends to send labor from
the one point to the other. The slowness with
which the change of method proceeds affords the time
that is necessary for the protection of labor in the
first-named group, since little movement takes place
before the effects of improvements made in the second
group begin to be felt. If in 1906 an improvement
is made which, in the course of five years, would
cause some labor to move from the subgroup A’’’
to the subgroup B’’’, and
in 1907 a corresponding improvement is made in the
latter industry, the equilibrium is restored before
enough disturbance has taken place to require any
absolute reduction of labor in A’’’.
The facts are (1) that new laborers as they enter the
field are drawn more to the upper subgroups than to
the lower ones, - to the A’’’
and the B’’’ rather than to
the A and the B of the two series, - and
that in moving upward they are drawn at first more
strongly toward B’’’ and later
more strongly toward A’’’.
This is the nearly constant fact in industry and is
the grand resultant of all the forces we have described - an
upward flow that is continuous but does not follow
strictly vertical lines. As young men - the
sons of workers in A, B, C, and
D, who might otherwise have remained in their
fathers’ occupation - move to the subgroups
that stand higher in the several series, they first
go in larger number toward B’’’
than toward A’’’, and later
in larger number toward A’’’.
There is a wavy movement toward the right and then
toward the left in the steady flow of labor from the
groups that create the raw material to those that
impart to these materials the form utilities which
they need to fit them for service. An actual
lessening of the number of workers in an entire group
in consequence of an improvement in the method of
production is practically unknown, and even a positive
lessening of the number in a subgroup is exceedingly
rare.
Apparent Exceptions to the Rule. - Exceptions
to this rule which are rather apparent than real will
occur to every one. The discovery of a great
supply of mineral oil put an end to the use of whale
oil for illuminating purposes, though it allowed the
whale fishery to survive on a reduced scale and produce
oil for other purposes, in so far as the rawest material,
the whales themselves, were not exterminated.
The exhaustion of a supply of raw material was here
a dominant fact, and the effects it produced may be
again expected when mineral oil shall, in turn, become
scarce. Men will move out of the subgroup producing
the crude oil, as nature forces them to do so, but
their movement cannot be referred merely to improvement
in the mode of extracting the oil or transporting
and refining it. The fact which illustrates the
rule we have stated is that while mineral oil drove
whale oil out of the field as an illuminant, this
did not reduce the number of men in the general group
which produces illuminating oil. More men were
set working in the oil fields than ceased working
on the whaling ships. A new raw material was
used in creating a similar finished product, and as
the general industry which made this product grew larger
rather than smaller, the total demand for labor in
oil production was not lessened. This does not
prove that old sailors did not suffer from the change.
Young sailors could go to the oil fields or elsewhere,
but men who were not adaptable could not do so, and
the hardship thus entailed is not to be overlooked.
We are, however, forming a judgment of movements which
pervade a vast industrial system, and we need most
to know what is their grand resultant. If that
were a general displacement of labor, causing increasing
idleness and suffering, the system that involved this
result would stand condemned. The general resultant
is the opposite of this.
A Drift of Labor toward Certain
General Groups. - We have just noticed
that movements of labor in the group system, caused
by improvements in method, consist mainly in an upward
flow of labor, accompanied by irregular lateral movements,
the labor drifting to the right or the left as it
is more strongly attracted now to one point and now
to another on the same horizontal plane. The general
mass of it swerves now to the right and now to the
left in its general ascending course, though none
may be actually expelled. This description of
the drift of labor is too general even to describe
all the permanent currents. Some entire groups
produce only or chiefly luxurious goods, and to those
there is the same drift of labor as there is to the
upper subgroups of the general series. If there
be a group of D’s making an article which
only the well-to-do can afford to use, it will swell
in size and in the volume of its output from the same
causes - improved methods and general enrichment - which
cause A’’’, B’’’,
and C’’’ to outgrow A,
B, and C.
Displacements of Mature Laborers
naturally tending to Diminish. - When
an improvement is made in one of the upper subgroups
while the general flow of labor is toward these groups,
the effect is not usually to lessen the absolute number
of workers in the upper subgroup where the improvement
has been made, but merely to prevent it from getting
a pro rata share of the labor that is moving
upward toward this tier of subgroups from the lower
ones. The change in the apportionment of the
social laboring force between the upper subgroups
and the lower ones is made gradually, without violent
transfers of particular men from point to point, and
merely by directing to the upper subgroups a disproportionate
number of young workers who are selecting their fields
of employment. In general, labor moves
from point to point in the system without requiring
many particular laborers to do so. As
actual loss of places by persons of mature age is
the chief evil connected with changes in methods of
production, it is a most welcome fact that the influence
which we are studying tends naturally to reduce the
extent of it.
The Discarding of Aged Laborers
mainly caused by a Further Influence. - Quite
apart from a demand for less labor at a particular
point in the system, there may occur a discharging
of men merely because of age and a substituting of
younger men. In establishments where the pace
is a rapid one men have thus to give place to young
successors at an earlier age than the one at which
men give place in other employments. The effect
of some machinery is to improve the chances of old
men, while that of other machinery is to reduce them.
A lightening of toil and a shortening of the working
day preserve men’s powers and enable them to
retain employment longer.
The Natural Tendency perverted
by Monopoly. - When hardships come on
a large scale in consequence of a discharging of workers,
they are chiefly due to an abnormal influence which
now shows itself in ugly and disquieting ways throughout
the industrial system, that, namely, of monopoly.
Reducing forces for the sake of curtailing production
and raising prices is what does the mischief.
This influence undoes at many points the beneficent
effects of free competition and causes grave hardships
to particular workers while affording no compensating
gain to the consuming public. It portends evil
for society as a whole as well as for the working
classes, on which its hand may be heavily laid.
In a perfectly natural system, in which competition
would do all that pure theory at the outset of this
study has assumed that it will do, the evil entailed
by local improvements would be relatively small and
the diffused benefits enormous. In proportion
as the movement approaches steadiness and as gains
are made, not by radical changes, now here, now there,
and now elsewhere, with long intervals between them,
but by smaller economies made nearly everywhere and
in very quick succession, the cause of the hardship
is reduced. There is less of violent expulsion
of labor from its fields and more of a gradual drifting
of labor rather than particular laborers from
the subgroups that create elementary products to those
which fashion them into fine and costly shapes.
There is small hardship in the natural selection by
new laborers of the employments where they are most
needed, and there is often little in a transfer of
a person who has tended a machine of one kind to a
machine of a different kind. Instances there still
are of manual skill brought to naught by the invention
of a mechanical automaton that does the work more
rapidly and accurately than the hand of man can do
it; and the worker who possesses this skill must usually,
in such cases, content himself with an employment where
his more general aptitudes may stand him in good stead
and insure him at least an average rate of pay.
The special aptitude which he had for performing one
operation counts for nothing; and this happens when
men who have worked in one department of a mill have
to accept work in other departments of the same mill
or in other employments.
A Workman’s Specific Loss
as compared with his Share of a Social Gain. - The
test question in cases like these is whether the man
is helped or harmed by the general effect of improvements,
including not only the one which has caused him to
change his occupation, but all others which have taken
place since he began working. To this question
there can be but one answer: in the course of
a lifetime the balance is in favor of progress even
in the case of the average victim of the movement,
and it is overwhelmingly so in the case of others.
What a man sacrifices when he is transferred from
one machine to another is usually more than offset
in a term of years by what he gains in consequence
of the general increase in the producing power of labor.
At the time of the displacement he suffers, but by
its constant increase in wealth and productivity society
more than atones for the injury. The goods that
emerge from the mills are multiplied; the share falling
to labor, as that share is determined by the test of
final productivity, grows steadily larger; and the
men who have never served a long apprenticeship at
anything, but have learned their present trades quickly
and can learn new ones as quickly, are producing and
getting far more than they could possibly get under
a regime of skilled manual labor or of inferior machinery,
and far more also than their successors will get hereafter
if, by any calamity, mechanical inventions shall cease
to be introduced and other product multipliers shall
be barred from the field. The hope of working
humanity lies mainly in the continuance of the changes
which give it a forever enlarging command over nature.
Some classes might live comfortably without this,
but for the worker it affords the main ground of hope
for increasing comfort and a coming time of general
abundance.