THE FOREGOING PRINCIPLES APPLIED TO THE RAILROAD PROBLEM
Simple Cases of Charging “What
the Traffic will Bear." - The value of
a study of primitive carriers and their policy lies
in the fact that it illustrates principles which apply
to transportation by a complicated system of railroads,
although in this latter case they are not easily discerned.
Imperfect competition is what exists in the department
of carrying. So long as a railroad is without
any rival it may, in some cases, charge for moving
goods from one point to another about as much as the
cost of making them at the latter point exceeds the
cost at the former. This is the simplest case
of charging what the traffic will bear. Or, again,
the situation may be dominated by producers at a third
point who can make goods and get them carried to the
place we may term the market for less than the cost
of making them directly in this latter place.
In such a case the road may demand nearly the amount
by which the cost of making the goods at an accessible
third point and moving them to the one which is their
market exceeds the cost of making them in the place
first named; and this is a slightly less simple case
of charging what the traffic will bear. It is
appropriating the difference between two natural values
neither of which the railroad itself fixes.
Charges based on Various Kinds
of Cost. - The charges of the railroad
may be limited by the competition of inferior carriers
who use its own route, such as teamsters whose wagons
use a public highway running parallel to its own track.
Here charges are based on costs, but not on those
which the railroad incurs. They are the costs
which the teamsters incur; and if the railroad has
much business, its own costs are less and it makes
a profit. The charges may be based on costs incurred
by more economical carriers, like owners of ships,
and in such a case the rate which the railroad can
get may be less than its own costs, if these are figured
in the simple way of dividing a total outlay by a
total number of units of freight transported.
The rate is based on the shipowners’ costs,
and these are so low as to bankrupt the railroad if
it should reduce all its charges to such a level.
It reduces them thus only on the particular route where
competition by water is encountered, and keeps them
elsewhere at the higher level. In the case of
shipments by rail over such routes “what the
traffic will bear” is determined by the low charges
established by the ships; and this means that it is
determined by a certain definite cost of carrying
goods between the very points which the railroad connects.
The Exceptional Importance of Fixed
Charges in the Case of Railroads. - The
railroad, in the case just noticed, carries its rates
below costs, as these are computed in a simple way,
but keeps the lowest of them somewhat above the variable
costs which we have defined; and there appears the
important fact that the fixed costs incurred by the
railroad form an unprecedentedly large part of its
total expenses. The interest on the outlay it
makes for roadbed, track, bridges, tunnels, terminals,
etc., is something for which there is no fair
parallel in the case of wagons or ships. This
is the first unique fact concerning railroads and
their policy; and the second is that they continue
very long in that intermediate state which we have
illustrated by the ship which had only a partial cargo
and was impelled to take some traffic at a special
and low rate. For many years the railroad only
partially utilizes its plant; and so long as that
is the case its natural policy is one of drastic discrimination
between different portions of its business. A
third great point of difference between the railroad
and other carriers appears if, while its capacity
is still only partially utilized, it encounters the
direct rivalry of other railroads that are eager for
business; competition then takes a shape which impels
the participants irresistibly into some kind of combination.
The union may be tacit or formal, and it may depend
on personal relations or on some merging of corporations;
but toward something that will make the rival lines
act concurrently and with mutual toleration the situation
impels them with unique force.
The general features of railroad rates, then, are -
(1) Some charges based on the difference
between the natural value of merchandise at the point
of origin and its value at the point of delivery,
as this latter value is determined by causes independent
of the rates charged for transportation between the
two points;
(2) The adjustment of other charges
according to costs incurred by independent carriers
operating between the same points;
(3) The exceptional importance of
the railroad’s “fixed costs” and
the drastically discriminating rates to which this
leads;
(4) The irresistible motive for combination
where direct competition appears between railroads
connecting the same points.
We speak of the condition of railroads
as an intermediate state because it is one out of
which a natural development takes other carriers when
their capacity for service is fully utilized.
The same cause - a complete utilization of
the plants - would have a like effect in
the case of railroads; but the cause is so slow in
coming into full operation that few persons think
of it as affecting the problem at all. The problem
of freight charges on railroads is usually regarded
as if the intermediate state were destined to be perpetual.
It is, however, entirely true that a full utilization
of the plants of railroads would tend to take them
out of this state. If the increase of business
came after a combination had been effected, it would
tend to put a stop to the sharp discriminations to
which the eager quest for traffic has led. Different
shippers could more easily secure equally favorable
treatment. Freight of a low grade would be less
desired, since the space it would require might otherwise
be available for business of a more profitable kind,
and the rates on such freight would rise. The
increased traffic would make it possible to earn large
dividends without increasing charges on the lower grades
of freight, and while greatly reducing the charges
on the higher grades; but no economic force would
be available for securing this adjustment. The
state, by positive regulation, might secure it and
might bring the earnings and the charges of the railroads
more or less nearly to the normal standards which
prevail where competition rules; but if competition
were here to begin, it would result quite otherwise.
It would restore the old condition of partially utilized
cars, track, etc., and cause a new strife for
traffic, which would cause some freight to be taken
at very low rates, but would lead to inevitable consolidation
and higher charges.
In general industry competition tends
so to adjust prices as to yield interest on capital,
wages for all varieties of labor, including labor
of management, and nothing more, and this is the outcome
elsewhere demanded by a growth of business coupled
with a theoretically normal and perfect action of
competition; but the peculiarities of competition
between railways do not bring about the evolution which
would give this result. Combination is effected
long before the returns from the total traffic are
made normal and before the returns from different
parts of it are brought into their legitimate relation
to each other. After the union of rival companies,
railroads continue to be in that intermediate state
in which the effect of an unused capacity for carrying
has its natural effect in charges which discriminate
widely between different localities and between different
kinds of freight. The railroad traffic does, indeed,
begin to follow the course which we have illustrated
in the case of transportation by water. It takes
a few steps in that direction, but further progress
is then stopped by combinations.
The fundamental laws of economics
still apply. The static standard of freight charges
exists, and one can form some idea of what actual
charges would be if the forces which elsewhere tend
to bring prices to their theoretical standards could
here operate unhindered. The hindrances, however,
are such as definitely to preclude such a result.
The rates do not become in a true sense normal.
Even under such active competition as at times exists
they do not become so, while without competition they
never tend to become so. It would, however, be
a gross mistake to assume that static standards have
no application whatever to railway transportation.
The whole subject is most easily understood when those
standards are first defined and the baffling influences
which prevent actual rates from conforming to them
are then separately studied. There are influences
which bring the various charges of railroads within
a certain definable distance of normal standards.
The situation of railroads we take
as we find it - one of complete consolidation
in case of many roads, and of harmonious action, or
quasi-consolidation, in the case of others. In
general their charges are fixed by the place value
they create, as that value is established by influences
other than the charges themselves. It might seem
that the charge for carrying fixes the place value.
Whatever a railroad demands for carrying goods from
A to B measures the enhanced value which they get
in the moving; but if they would have possessed at
B the same value that they now have, even though the
railroad had not existed at all, it is evident that
it is this value minus the value of the goods at A
which fixes the charges for carrying, rather than that
these charges fix the place value. We have seen
in very simple and general cases how this principle
works, and have now very briefly to trace the working
of it in the case of a system of railroads. The
special method of reckoning costs to which we have
referred is an important element in the process.
"Costing” comparatively Simple
in the Bookkeeping of Competing Producers. - In
the study of ordinary industries we have encountered
conditions which render the bookkeeping of a producer
simple and cause him to charge all his costs, in a
pro rata fashion, to his entire product.
If his goods and those of his rivals are of one kind
and are sold in a single market, a cut in the price
of any one portion of the product involves a corresponding
cut on the entire output. It is not possible
to single out any particular increment for a reduction
of price and leave the rate unchanged on the remainder.
Where products are of different kinds it is possible
to make a classification of them so as to get a large
profit on some, a small one on others, and none at
all on still others. When competition has not
done its full work, something of this kind happens
in many departments of business. A condition
of unequal gain from different portions of an output
lingers long after some effects of competition have
been realized. In the end, however, it must yield
if competition itself does its complete work, and
whenever we adhere heroically to the hypothesis of
the static state, we preclude this inequality of charges.
Rivals who contend with each other for profitable
business bring the prices of the goods which afford
the most gain to such a level that a mill which makes
this type of goods will pay no more in proportion
to its capital than one which makes other types.
The total cost of production, fixed and variable alike,
would at that time, as we have seen, be barely covered,
and might correctly be apportioned in a pro rata
manner among all parts of the product.
The Effect of Increasing Business
on Comparative Charges. - Competition
of this perfect kind does not exist in manufacturing
and is far from existing in the department of carrying,
and it is important to know whether with growing business
and greatly tempered rivalry there is any tendency
toward the equalization of charges and the simplifying
of the mode of reckoning costs. When a mill has
more orders than it can fill, those it wishes to be
rid of are the ones which yield the smallest profit.
They encumber the mill and prevent the filling of
more profitable orders; and the natural mode of reducing
the amount of this undesirable part of the output is
to raise the charges on it. This comes about without
much aid from competition, for when all producers
find their capacity overtaxed, they have no motive
for contending sharply for business. Underbidding
has for its purpose attracting business from rivals
and is an irrational operation when all have orders
enough and to spare. Competition is largely in
abeyance when the business any one can have is overabundant.
These Principles Applicable to
Carrying. - What we here assert concerning
goods manufactured by independent mills would be true
of goods carried by independent vessels, if they plied
between the same two ports with no intermediate stops.
If their capacity should at any time be overtaxed,
they would not reduce the charges on higher grades,
but they would raise them on the lower grades, and
the classification of freight would lose some of its
significance. The lowering of the charges on
the high grades of freight would come when the profits
of the business should attract new carriers, who would
naturally seek for the traffic that paid the best,
till all kinds paid about alike. The mode of
reckoning costs might then become simple - a
pro rata division of total outlays among all
parts of the business.
The Condition of Uniform Costing
never realized upon Railroads. - Not
a single one of the essential conditions of equalized
charges and uniform costing is now realized upon railroads,
and there is only one of them that is approximated.
Separate markets for different parts of the traffic
are provided by the nature of the business. Every
point to which goods are conveyed furnishes such a
distinct market, and the service of carrying goods
to it is paid for by a distinct set of customers.
It follows, therefore, that some rates can be cut without
affecting others, and they regularly are so. The
second condition, that of bringing the carrying capacity
of railroads into the fullest possible use, is attainable,
but it is very remote. At times there is a congestion
of freight and, in general, the capacity of existing
plants is more nearly used than it heretofore has been;
but by an addition to the rolling stock they could
carry more than they do and the additional traffic
would cost far less than the portion already carried.
Moreover, with no addition to the rolling stock, very
considerable enlargements of traffic could at many
points be made. Thirdly, competition between
railroads is not at present effective enough to bring
about a reduction of the higher charges and make returns
and costs simple. Combination takes place long
before the discriminating charges are abandoned.
Low-grade freight continues to be carried side by
side with the high-grade which pays better. Charges
to terminal points continue to be low, while charges
to intermediate points are high. In a sense one
may say that a tendency to discontinue these practices
exists, but it is a tendency that is so effectually
resisted that its natural results are only in small
part realized. If a dam is built across a reservoir,
holding the waters on one side ten feet above those
on the other, one may say that the waters have a tendency
to reach a uniform level, since the power of gravity
is exercised in that direction; but the dam baffles
the tendency. And so in railroad operations something
interferes which checks the force of competition or
removes it altogether, long before the discriminations
in freight charges are removed or very much reduced.
An Intermediate State made relatively
Permanent. - As we have said, the condition
of traffic on railroads is analogous to what in the
case of manufacturers and primitive carriers would
be regarded as a transitional state soon to be left
behind; but in the case of railroads it is relatively
permanent. It is the condition in which certain
natural economic forces are working vigorously, and,
if they were not counteracted by other forces, would
end by making natural adjustments and establishing
normal rates for the carrier as well as the manufacturer.
In this intermediate state the natural forces are
counteracted and the adjustments are never made, and
what we have to study is the degree in which they
are approximated.
A Simple Case of Special Costing
Applied to Certain Traffic. - We will
suppose A and B are connected by a railroad, while
C and B are connected by a highway over which transportation
proceeds by the primitive means of horses and wagons.
It is like one of the cases we have already stated,
with the exception of the fact that the carrier over
the longer route is a railroad. The limit of what
the railroad can get is the natural difference between
the cost of making the goods at A and the combined
costs of making them at C and carrying them to B.
This definitely limits the railroad charges. Whatever
difference of cost there is the railroad can get if
it chooses, and barring any deduction it may make
in order to induce production at A and make traffic
for itself, it will get it. The rate which is
fixed for the railroad may be sufficient to cover
the total costs chargeable to this portion of its
traffic on the simple and pro rata plan of costing,
or on the other hand, it may cover only a portion of
the fixed costs or no portion at all. This means
that the standard which is set by the differing values
of the goods at A and at B may or may not yield a
profit to the railroad. If it is so slight as
not to cover even the variable costs of carrying the
goods, the railroad will not carry them, and the supply
will be allowed to come from C rather than from A.
If it covers more than these variable costs, the road
will accept and carry the goods. If the traffic
affords any appreciable margin above the variable
costs, it will be the policy of the railroad to make
its charges low enough to attract the traffic, and
this will slightly reduce the place value of the goods
at B and bring it below the cost of procuring them
from C. The railroad will thus secure the whole traffic
to the exclusion of that which came from C. If the
costs of making the goods at A and C are alike, then
the charge for carrying from A to B will be just enough
below the total costs of carrying in wagons from C
to B to stop the carrying over this shorter route and
appropriate the whole business; but this charge may
not cover total costs of carrying from A. It may yield
only a slight margin above the variable costs attaching
to this part of the railroad’s business.
It thus appears that this carrier can with advantage
accept the freight at a rate that by a perfectly normal
bookkeeping is below cost, while the teamsters on
the road from C cannot do this.
A Second Case in which Carrying
is done for Any Amount above Variable Cost. - Let
us now suppose there is a railroad from C to B as well
as one from A to B. There is now competition between
makers at A and carriers from A to B, on the one hand,
and makers at C and carriers from C to B, on the other
hand; and whichever of these quasi-partnerships delivers
the goods at B at the cheaper rate gets the whole
traffic. By the terms of our supposition the makers
in both places are offering goods at cost, and any
cutting of rates that is to be done must be done by
the carriers. To reduce the prices of the goods
at the mills in either locality would put some of them
out of business. We will assume that there is
no consolidation and no other means of concurrent
action between the railroads, and that the whole traffic
will thus go to the route over which the lower rates
are made. For simplicity we will still adhere
to the supposition of equal costs for manufacturing
and of unequal costs for carrying. As the charge
for carrying goes down, one or the other of the railroads
will reach the point where the variable costs of this
traffic are barely covered, while on the other line
they are more than covered. Where rivalry is
not tempered in any way whatever, the charge made by
competing roads falls to a level at which returns
only cover the variable costs incurred by one of the
competitors, though it may return somewhat more in
the case of the other.
How Fixed Costs are Met. - This
implies, indeed, that the fixed charges of both roads
must somehow be met by the returns from other traffic;
and this supposition is in accordance with the facts.
A freight war may temporarily carry rates to a level
where some traffic does not cover variable costs and
where total traffic falls short of covering total
costs. Such a situation cannot long continue,
and the natural adjustment, under active competition,
is one at which rates on the traffic for which the
two lines are contending are just below the variable
costs incurred by one line but above those incurred
by the other. There is nothing to prevent the
stronger railroad from thus reducing its rates, attracting
to itself the whole of the traffic, and putting an
end to the rivalry of the other line. This would
mean bankruptcy for that line unless it had other
sources of income.
The Effects of Bankruptcy on Costs. - Bankruptcy
means a scaling down of the fixed charges of the railroad
to such a point that the total traffic can meet them;
but it does not enable the company to reacquire business
that will not yield enough to cover variable costs.
Adhering to the supposition that there is no mutual
understanding, no pool, and no other approach to consolidation
between the rival lines, we may safely say that the
general rule which elsewhere governs rates holds true
here. Two roads actively competing for identically
the same traffic tend to bring charges to a level
at which the variable charges entailed by this traffic
on the one route are not quite met and the traffic
passes to the other line.
A Principle governing Competition
between Railroads and Carriers by Sea. - In
a third case there may be between A and B a railroad
and a water route also, while between C and B there
is a railroad only. On the supposition we have
made, - that competition between carriers
by water has done its full work, - the charge
for carrying anything by water from A to B must be
sufficient to cover a pro rata part of the
total costs. That may be sufficient to cover the
merely variable costs entailed on the railroad, or
it may not. If it does not, the railroad will
not take any portion of the business except what it
may take by reason of the greater speed with which
it can transport the goods. If, however, the
total costs of carrying by water exceed by a tolerable
margin the merely variable costs of carrying by land,
the railroad will be able to take the traffic.
If this traffic goes to the water route, the charge
made by the railroad from C to B is adjusted by a
simple rule. This railroad can get the natural
difference between the cost of the goods at C and
the cost of similar ones made at A and carried by
water to B. If the railroad gets the traffic between
A and B, and the water route is abandoned, the case
becomes the same as that which we have already considered, - the
transporting is done at a rate which prevents one
of the lines from covering its merely variable costs
and secures all the traffic for the other line.
The carrying from A to B goes by land or by water
according as the variable costs, in the one case,
or the pro rata share of total costs, in the
other, are the less; and nothing can be carried from
C to B unless it can be delivered at B at a price
as low as that of goods made at A and transported
at the rate just described. If the costs of making
at A and C are equal and there are the three carriers
seeking traffic, as assumed, the result naturally
is to give all the business to the one who will bid
the lowest for it. Either railroad will bid as
low as the variable costs which the traffic occasions;
while the owners of ships will bid no lower than the
rate which covers costs of both kinds.
The Case of Railroads having Common
Terminal Points. - In the fourth case
there are, besides the other carriers, two railroads
between A and B which compete for the traffic at these
terminal points, but not at intermediate ones.
Their facilities for through traffic are alike.
The local traffic on the different lines is unlike,
since it is affected by the character of the regions
through which the railroads pass; but the charges
made for local traffic are governed by the comparatively
simple principles which we first stated. In contending
for freight to way stations we may say that the railroad
has to compete with wagons upon the highway, but with
nothing more efficient. The charges for local
freight may therefore be extremely high, while, if
the railroads are really competing as vigorously as
pure theory requires, and if the normal results of
competition are completely realized, the rate which
can be maintained between A and B for any articles
carried will be no higher than those which cover the
variable costs entailed on the route which is the
less economical of the two. The line to which
this test assigns the traffic between A and B must
then stand the further tests we have described - those
involved in contending for business with carriers
using respectively the water route and the railroad
from C to B.
A Condition leading to a Reduction
of Fixed Costs. - It is safe to assume
that one of the two railroads from A to B has more
local traffic than the other. It may be that
even with this advantage its total returns of all
kinds may fall short of covering its total outlays.
In that case the total returns of any less favorable
route must fall still further short of the amount
necessary for covering all outlays; and if we adhere
to the assumption that neither consolidation nor anything
resembling it takes place, we have a case in which
both railroads must undergo reorganization. The
fixed charges of the better route must be scaled down
and the creditors of this railroad must accept the
loss, while on the other route the fixed charges must
be reduced still more and the creditors must suffer
a larger loss. It goes without saying that the
prospect of such a calamity means consolidation.
It is evident what alternative competitors face in
cases in which heroic competition goes on to the bitter
end. As a rule this is an unrealized alternative.
The mere prospect of the calamity connected with it
is bad enough to put an end to the independent action
of the different railroads. With the facilities
for combination which now exist a far smaller inducement
suffices to bring this about.
The Case of Railroads whose Entire
Routes are Parallel. - We have to consider
only one more typical case in order to have before
us a sufficient number to establish the general principles
which govern the charges for the carrying of freight
by railroads. Variations innumerable might be
stated; and, indeed, the experience of the railroad
system of this country affords the variations and reveals
the results which follow from the conditions they
create. The railroads may be strictly parallel
lines, pursuing the same route and competing for local
traffic as well as for through traffic. If the
case we lately examined insures consolidation, - and
indeed all of the cases we have stated impel the companies
powerfully toward it, - this last case makes
assurance doubly sure. Strictly parallel railroads
competing for traffic over their entire routes and
neither uniting nor showing any of the approaches
to union would be an impossibility. Persistent
competition would then mean reducing all charges to
the level fixed by variable costs, which would leave
no revenue whatever to cover fixed costs, and would
send the companies into a bankruptcy from which even
reorganizations could not relieve them, since they
could not annihilate all the fixed costs.
A Case of Arrested Development. - It
is clear that, in the entire policy of railroads,
the fact that their capacity has never been fully
used plays a highly important part. It makes the
distinction between fixed costs and variable ones
a leading element in the adjustment of charges.
With the capacity of railroads completely used, as
is that of a ship which carries a full cargo at every
voyage, the distinction would lose most of its importance.
More business would then require an addition to every
part of the plant and would thus entail new fixed
costs which would have to be charged against the new
business. As the traffic of any railroad grows
toward its maximum, the cost which each separate addition
to it entails grows larger and larger. When cars
are few and are only half filled, an increment of
traffic entails a very small increment of expense.
When the cars are filled and new freight requires
the purchase of more of them, the cost of this addition
to the traffic becomes greater. When further
additions to the freight carried require additions
to trackage, yard room, storage room, etc., they
cost far more than the earlier additions; and new increments
of freight come, in the end, to cost very nearly as
much per unit as the general body of the previous
traffic when all outlays were charged against it.
The railroad approaches the condition of the full ships
referred to, in which further cargoes require further
ships, with all the outlays which this implies.
The distinction between different kinds of costing
is gradually obliterated, and railroads steadily draw
nearer to that ultimate state which other carriers
more quickly approach, in which each part of the freight
carried must bear its share of the total costs entailed.
Long before that state is reached, however, combination
ensues, and the movement of freight charges toward
their static standard is arrested.
The Standard of Freight Charges
under a Regime of Monopoly. - A consolidation
so complete that it would merge all rival lines under
a single board of control and pool all their earnings
would restore the early condition described in connection
with one of our illustrations - that of the
single railroad between A and B, having only sailing
vessels and wagons as rivals. It is able to charge
what the traffic will bear in a simple and literal
sense. The consolidated lines can, if they choose,
get for each bit of carrying the difference between
the value of goods at the point where they are taken
and their value at the point where they are delivered.
These values are approximately what they would be
if no railroad existed. The carrying done by
the railroad itself does not enter into the making
of them. The natural value of a commodity at
A is what it costs to make it there, and the value
at B is either the cost of making it at B, or that
of making it at C and carrying it in wagons to B, or
that of making it at A and carrying it by water to
B. In any case there is a natural and simple process
of fixing the costs both at A and at B, and the difference
between them is the limit up to which the railroad
can push its charges if it will. Where the business
which furnishes the freight is not fully developed,
the railroad may moderate its charges for the sake
of letting it grow larger. The hope of increased
traffic in the future may cause a reduction of demands
in the present. We shall see what other influences
may keep the charges below their possible level; but
the natural difference between two local values of
goods is the basis of the charge for carrying them
from one point to the other. Consolidated lines,
if they had as perfect a monopoly of carrying by railroad
as has the single line in our illustration, would
base their charges on this simple principle, though
for a number of reasons they might not take all that
the principle would allow.
How Imperfect Consolidation Works. - Imperfect
consolidation, when it follows a period of sharp competition,
has to deal with obstacles which prevent a complete
carrying out of this policy. Many rates have
become far lower than the rule of monopoly would make
them, and there are difficulties in the way of raising
them. A weak combination of parallel lines may
keep its charges within bounds, partly from a fear
that larger ones may afford too great an incentive
to secret rate cutting and may so break up the union,
and partly from a respect for what the people may
do if the exactions of the railroads become too great.
The more complete forms of consolidation have not the
former of these dangers to fear; and if, without being
restrained by the state, their charges continue moderate,
it is mainly due to the fact that other lines less
firmly consolidated are unable safely to make a radical
advance of rates, and that this often prevents such
a course in the case of lines which would otherwise
be able to take it.
Limits on the Charges of a System
of strongly Consolidated Lines. - This
means that where a great system of railroads occupying
the whole of a vast territory is so firmly consolidated
as to have a complete monopoly of carrying by rail
within the area, it is still affected in indirect
ways by the possible rivalry of lines altogether outside
of its territory. An excessive charge on freight
from Chicago to New York might induce carrying by
rail from Chicago to Norfolk and thence by water to
New York. It might cause grain, flour, etc.,
to be shipped to Europe from Southern ports rather
than from those on the Atlantic coast. These
cases and others do not fall under principles essentially
different from those already stated, but they call
for the application of the same principles in complex
conditions which our study is too brief to cover.
There is a supposable case in which nearly all that
could be secured by any railroad connecting Chicago
with the Atlantic coast, even though every line in
the territory between them were the property of one
corporation, would be the variable cost of carrying
goods over a line running to a port on the Gulf of
Mexico. Reflection will easily show how the principles
already stated apply to this case and others.
Effects of a General and Strong
Consolidation. - With all the lines in
this country and Canada in a strong consolidation,
the advance of rates to, or well toward, the limit
set by the principle of natural place value created
would inevitably come unless the power of the state
should in some way prevent it. The railroads would
be able to get the difference between the cost of
goods at A, in the illustrative case, and the cost
of making or procuring them at B without using the
connecting line of railroad. When the appeal to
the state is only imminent, - when the power
of the government is not yet exercised, but impends
over every railroad that establishes unreasonable
charges, - the rates may be held in a fair
degree of restraint. A wholesome respect for
the possibilities of lawmaking here takes the
place of actual statutes. A respect for the law
appears in advance of its enactment and may amount
to submitting rates in an imperfect and irregular
way to the approval of the state. This effect,
when it is realized, is to be credited in part to
laws which will never be enacted. The merely
potential law - that which the people will
probably demand if they are greatly provoked, but
not otherwise - may be a stronger deterrent
than the prospect of more moderate legislation.
In general a considerable part of the economic lawmaking
of the future will undoubtedly be called out by demands
for action that is too violent to be taken except
under great provocation. The dread of the extreme
penalty insures a cautious policy in increasing charges
which have been established under a transient regime
of competition. Partial monopolies adhering to
rates many of which were established under the pressure
of competition - such are the railroad systems
of America. The existing condition shows some
of the effects of competition which has ceased and
of legislation which has not taken place. As the
combinations shall become greater and stronger, the
situation everywhere will become more and more akin
to that which existed in a local way when a single
line of railroad had no effective competition, and
the charges which the traffic would bear were fixed
in the way we have described and absorbed the place
value which the carrying created. It is a method
which exposes the public to an extortion which, though
not unlimited, is unendurably great. Consolidation,
therefore, means the control of rates by the state;
but it is essential that this control be exercised
with due regard for the economic principles which
rule in this department of industry. Thus only
can there be secured the results of a natural system
unperverted by monopoly.
The principles which a study of simple cases suffices to
establish are as follows: -
1. Freight charges are essentially
a variety of price. They express the exchange
value of place utility.
2. The static standards or norms
toward which these prices tend are fixed in the same
way as are other static standards of value, - by
a rule of cost, - though in the case of railroads
the working of this rule is exceptional.
3. When carrying is done by simple
means and by competing carriers, the ultimate basis
of charges is the cost of the carrying; and this is
estimated in the simple way in which, under perfectly
free competition, the cost of making commodities is
estimated. The total outlay is charged against
the total product.
4. A single railroad between
one point and another, when it is not affected by
the rivalry of any other railroad, can get for its
service the difference between the cost of goods at
the place where they are made and the cost at the
point of delivery, on the supposition that they would
either be made at this point or carried thither by
more primitive means. Under such a partial monopoly
the costs incurred by the railroad itself do not directly
set the standard of its charges, but other costs do
so.
5. In this case the so-called
variable costs incurred by the railroad furnish a
minimum limit below which its charges cannot go, but
to which they tend to go in the case of traffic which
cannot otherwise be secured.
6. This place value which the
railroad can confer on the goods is small (1) when
the cost of making the goods at their place of departure
is not much less than that of making them at their
place of destination, or (2) when it is not much less
than the cost of obtaining them from a third point,
or (3) when it is possible to carry them from the
place of their origin to their destination by water
or by any other cheap means of transportation.
7. Variable costs are positive
additions to the total outlays previously incurred
by a railroad, and they result from adding a definite
amount to its previous traffic. They are less
than proportionate parts of total costs, including
interest, some part of operating expenses, cost of
maintenance of roadway, etc.
8. The comparative smallness
of the variable costs is chiefly due to the fact that
the carrying capacity of railroads is only partially
used. These costs become relatively larger as
traffic increases, and would practically coincide
with proportionate shares of total costs if the traffic
should reach its absolute maximum.
9. If the place value above defined
is large enough to cover the variable costs attaching
to certain traffic and afford any surplus whatever,
the railroad usually takes this traffic.
10. On the business which it
gets the charges vary widely and, as it appears, capriciously,
but they are at bottom governed by the economic principle
stated - that of place value as established
in ways in which the charges of the railroad itself
do not figure.
11. Competing railroads tend
to bring rates downward toward a minimum which is
fixed by the merely variable costs of the carrying
as done by one or more of the railroads themselves.
12. The competition between railroads
is arrested while they are not using their full capacity,
while the merely variable costs of an increment of
traffic are still abnormally low, and while many rates
are so.
13. Railroads which compete for
freight between terminal points are strongly impelled
toward consolidation; and those which compete along
their entire lines are forced to resort to it.
14. Consolidation in its more
imperfect forms tends to establish rates that are
abnormally high, but this tendency is somewhat checked
by the danger that the combination may be broken by
a desire to foster business in a section of country
and by the indirect influence of lines outside of
the territory controlled by the consolidated roads.
15. In its stronger and more
extended forms consolidation leaves the people with
no adequate safeguard against extortionate charges
except as this is furnished by the intervention of
the state; and this needs to be effected with an intelligent
regard for the natural forces which are at work amid
the seemingly capricious irregularities in the present
system of charges.
The Aim of Regulation by the State. - An
aim of a government, in all of its economic policy,
is to insure the best use of the national resources,
and this can often be done by keeping alive free competition.
Where the rivalry of producers is active, a law of
survival guarantees that the more economical method
of producing an article shall displace the inferior
one. When the choice lies between using a quantity
of free and disposable labor in making goods in a
certain market and using it in making them elsewhere
and carrying them to the market, the alternative which
gives society the most that it can get by any use
of its productive resources is the one that is spontaneously
selected.
How an Extortionate Local Charge
may sometimes be reduced without Injury to a Railroad. - A
low charge for freight carried from A to B coupled
with an extortionate one from A’ to B might preclude
making the goods at A’, though they can be made
there at excellent advantage and the interests of
society will soon require that they be so. This
situation can exist only so long as traffic is slight
between A and A’ and greater between A’
and B. The growth of traffic over the former section
of the route will make it desirable for the railroad
to raise its rate over that portion. If, under
compulsion or otherwise, it reduces the rate from
A’ to B sufficiently to permit the production
of the goods at A’, it will gain a profitable
traffic between A’ and B at the cost of giving
up a relatively unprofitable one between A and B.
Variable Costs a Proper Basis for
Some Charges. - It makes for general
economy to pay respect to the distinction between fixed
and variable costs and let much freight be carried
for anything it will yield above the variable ones.
If ten units of labor are required for making an article
at B and only five at A, and if a railroad between
these points, whose capacity is not fully utilized,
can carry the article from A to B with an expenditure
of two additional units of labor, then society can
best get the goods for use at B by spending these
seven units in the making and carrying. It would
take ten units to make them at B, and to society itself
there is a saving of three units from making them
at A and carrying them at a special rate to B. Till
the railroad is more fully used for other purposes
this source of economy will continue. Though
the rates charged for this freight would bankrupt
the railroad if they were applied to its entire traffic,
it is best for the railroad to take this special bit
of carrying at any rate exceeding the wages of the
two units of labor; and for the time being this is
the best way to use some of the social resources, since
it gives at the point of delivery and use more goods
for a given outlay than could have been had in any
other way.
Why Consumers may suffer while
Particular Producers may be Favored. - It
will be seen that this principle affords an inducement
for making a special classification of certain goods
and carrying them for less than merchandise of a generally
similar kind is carried for. It is a policy of
“making traffic” which costs little and
is worth more than it costs both to the carrier and
to society. This incentive for reducing charges
does not operate as strongly in the case of goods
carried to consumers who are forced to live on the
route. They are held there by the general causes
mentioned at the beginning of the preceding chapter,
and must pay the tax which the railroad imposes on
them. The only limit on this tax is the possibility
of otherwise procuring the goods or of moving out
of the territory. The ultimate possibility that
population may not grow under a regime of extortion
and that both freight traffic and passenger traffic
may be held within small limits imposes some check
on the railroad’s exactions. The company
may find it worth while to foster to some extent the
growth of population; and to favor producers of certain
goods in order to induce them to locate their establishments
on its line, and the result of this may be good for
society; but there is no way of securing a general
good from the heavy tax on the rest of the traffic
unless this has been necessary to insure the existence
of the railroad itself. In that case there may
be a temporary necessity for it, which will disappear
as traffic grows.
The Policy of the State in Dealing
with Low Charges based on Variable Costs. - The
interest of railroads which have a monopoly of their
routes is to advance the rates on through traffic.
We have noticed a possible case in which some equalization
of charges by occasional reductions of local rates
takes place. An increase of charges over long
routes not made necessary by any pressure of business
which overtaxes the railroad’s carrying power
would of course be injurious. Moreover, carrying
full loads does not constitute such an overtaxing
as calls for the higher rates. There are times
when present supplies of cars and engines may not
be able to move more freight than they do; but in
that case more of them are called for. Only when
the point is reached at which providing for this through
traffic in addition to the local freight entails additions
to the permanent plant and involves costs that exceed
the return from the through business, is it justifiable,
in the interest of social efficiency, to advance such
charges. In preventing such an advance under other
conditions a government helps to secure an approach
to a natural economy and a maximum of production.
When, in the Interest of General
Productivity, a Reduction of Local Charges is called
for. - We saw that carriers of a primitive
kind competing with each other would put every charge,
local or otherwise, on a basis of its proportionate
share of total costs. The traffic as a whole
would return enough to cover all the outlays, and each
part of it would yield its share. This is the
ideal of effectiveness for railroads, as well as for
ships and wagons. The attainment of the ideal
without a regulation of charges by the state is never
to be expected. One feature of this normal condition
is that, where no special improvements have recently
been made, total returns should just equal total costs,
in the sense in which terms are used in static theory - that
sense in which all interest charges and all expenses
of management figure among the costs. No net
profit for the entrepreneur, but full interest
for the capitalist and full wages for all varieties
of labor, is the rule that gives the static measure
of normal returns. If a state shall slowly reduce
the charges for local freight, while holding unchanged
those for through traffic, - all the while
allowing the total returns of the railroads to cover
what we have defined as total costs, - it
will do all it can toward securing an approximation
to the condition which affords the largest product
of social industry. It will help to make the
resources of the people do their utmost in yielding
an income. Total returns covering all costs,
a reduction of those charges on local traffic which
have prevented industries from springing up at intermediate
points between favored centers, a gradual increase
of local production without any positive repression
of production elsewhere - such are some features
of the general change which the future should bring
and which only the power of the state can make it
bring.
How the State may secure what Competition
secures in Other Fields. - In general
industry the rivalry of entrepreneurs carries prices
to a level fixed by costs, but in transportation the
rivalry has so largely disappeared as to prevent such
an outcome. The state cannot restore much of
the vanished rivalry and would cause an unnatural
condition if it did so. We have seen toward what
an abnormal level of costs a sharp “freight
war” carries rates. What the state can
do is something which an instinctive judgment of the
people is impelling it to do; namely, to adjust rates
directly and bring them gradually toward the standard
to which competition, if it were working as it elsewhere
works, would automatically bring them, namely, that
at which wages and interest are fully covered.
A surplus above these outlays could always be temporarily
secured wherever a special economy had been effected,
and the source of legitimate profit would be open
to carriers as it is to producers generally. How
much should be reckoned as interest depends on the
question how the capital itself is estimated, and
here again the instinct of the people has been correct.
It will not accept as a measure of true capital the
market value of all the stocks and bonds the railroad
has issued. The quotations of the market make
the total values of the stocks and bonds equal a capitalization
of its total earnings, and these may include a profit
due to monopoly. If a state were to figure the
capital in this way, and then so adjust rates as to
allow ordinary interest on the sum thus computed,
it would merely leave total returns as they are.
It might change comparative charges, but not the sum
total of all of them.
How Capital should be Estimated. - In
that static condition in which, as we have shown,
capital is as productive in one subgroup as in another,
the capital is first measured by the cost of the goods
that, in the inception of the industry, embody it,
and in static studies this cost is regarded as constant.
Returns from different outlays are equalized, and
a dollar invested in one kind of business then yields
as much in a year as a dollar in any other. In
a dynamic state the cost standard still prevails,
and as the tools of production become cheaper, in
terms of labor, it takes more of them to represent
the same amount of capital that was originally invested.
What it would at any time cost to duplicate every
item in the equipment of a business measures the capital
it uses. Nothing but a failure of competition
in the case of railroads prevents the application
of this standard to them. Monopoly makes earnings
more or less independent of sums invested and causes
purchasers to buy stock at rates that are independent
of costs of plant and equipment and are fixed by earnings
themselves.
The Process of Estimating Capital
on the Basis of Cost. - If we undertake
here to do by public authority what competition elsewhere
tends to do, we shall have to restore the standard
based, not on the original cost of the railroad’s
substantial property, but on the cost of getting another
that would be equal to it in working efficiency.
The plant is worth what it would naturally cost to
duplicate it; and an average rate of interest on that
sum is the natural return from it. There are
ethical claims which are entitled to respect and which
preclude any sudden reduction of the value of a railroad’s
properties; and, moreover, the end in view can be
attained in a way that will not necessarily take anything
from the absolute amount which they are now worth.
If the amount of dividends remains fixed, the increase
in the actual value of the plant itself will bring
these dividends into the proper ratio to it.
The land that the companies use is becoming more valuable.
Measured by what it would cost to duplicate it, it
represents a larger and larger amount on the companies’
inventories. If the equipment also is enlarged
as traffic grows, the entire sum on which interest
and dividends are computed becomes continually larger.
If the interest and dividends earned by the plants
now in existence remain fixed in absolute amount,
they will become a smaller and smaller percentage
of the real capital of the companies. Merely
letting railroads earn the amount that they do at present
would bring the net incomes after some years to the
same rate - the same percentage of invested
capital - that the income from other capital
represents. New plants and enlargements of old
ones should be allowed to earn enough to furnish an
incentive for providing them as fast as the needs
of the public require it.
How Insuring a Fixed Amount of
Total Earnings would affect the Rates charged for
Freight. - It goes without saying that
the general increase of traffic, while the freight
charges remain the same, increases the net earnings
of the carrying companies. Therefore the policy
of keeping the net earnings at a fixed total amount
would mean a reduction of rates for freight and passenger
service. We do not here raise the question how
much reduction will be required for the purpose in
view - that of transferring to the people
at large whatever now constitutes a genuine monopoly
profit. In the case of some lines there is, it
is safe to say, no such profit, and it will be impossible
to tell how much of it elsewhere exists till some
careful appraisal of plants and equipments, on the
basis of the cost of duplicating them, shall have
been made. What we need to know is that, by the
aid of such an appraisal, the state can, if it will,
secure in the department of carrying the result which
is automatically secured elsewhere, namely, the prevalence
of charges which afford normal returns on invested
capital as well as wages for every kind of labor.
Elements of the Problem not included
in a merely Economic Study. - It will
not fail to occur to any reader that in making the
present study of railroads a very general and purely
economic one we leave out of account some facts of
great importance. We take no account of corruption
within the corporations which do the carrying, nor
of corruption in the relation between them and the
officials of the state. Stockholders within the
corporation are likely to have their interests betrayed
by those who are appointed to take charge of them,
and citizens of the state are likely to have their
greater interests betrayed, in a like manner, by their
appointed custodians. We cannot here discuss
the various plans by which directors plunder their
own corporations, nor the ways in which public officials
betray the people. All of these abuses are disturbing
influences in the economic system; and all of them
interfere with the adjustment which gives the highest
productive efficiency, and contribute a full share
toward putting the social order in danger. All
are, however, so obviously criminal, if they are judged
by the spirit of the law, - not to say by
the letter of it, - that it is better to leave
the discussion of the mode of suppressing them to
legal and political science.
A Practical Mode of Insuring an
Approach to Normal Rates for Transportation. - When
competition rules, it enlarges the supply of a dear
article till the price of it is normal, and it increases
the capital in a profitable business till its earnings
become so. In the case of railroads this does
not automatically take place, but the result of it
all - adequate service and normal charges
for it - can be directly secured by the state.
Charges that have been made reasonable by competition
may be left as they are, and those that are disproportionately
high may be gradually lowered. The growth of
traffic may be trusted to keep the total earnings of
the companies’ present plants at the amount
at which they now stand, in spite of these reductions
of rates; and enlargements of the plants may be permitted
to earn further sums which will attract capital and
keep the service abreast of the public need.
All this will require expert skill of a very high
order. For the purpose of the present work it
is enough to say that such a course as this is the
only one which will insure in transportation the results
which competition elsewhere yields. It will secure
both rates and service which the civil law calls “reasonable”
and economic law calls “natural.”