Europe and Asia The United States Reciprocity
The early years of the Laurier regime
brought Canada into the visual range of the outside
world. During the middle years the business of
the country’s internal development overshadowed
everything else. Then in the later years the
relations of Canada with other countries came to occupy
an increasingly important place on the political stage.
At last, Canada’s rising star
compelled the attention of foreign countries beyond
the seas. Some of these countries sent capital,
and no Canadian objected. Some sent goods, and
manufacturers and producers raised the questions of
protection and reciprocal tariff privileges.
Others, as we have seen, sent men. Some of these
immigrants Canada welcomed indiscriminately, some
she took with qualms, while against others she erected
high barriers, with half a mind to make them still
higher.
First, as to trade and tariffs, which
were the chief subjects of discussion with European
governments. The original Fielding tariff of
1897 had adopted the minimum and maximum principle,
with the intention that a few low-tariff countries
should share with Great Britain the advantages of
the lower rates. Treaty complications made this
impossible, and the lower rates were confined to the
Empire. Then in 1907 came the intermediate tariff
as a basis for bargaining. The Government turned
first to France. Mr Fielding and Mr Brodeur,
associated with the British ambassador at Paris, negotiated
a treaty, giving France the intermediate and in some
cases still lower rates, and receiving advantages
in return. The treaty, though made in 1907, was
not ratified until 1910. Owing to existing British
treaties with most-favoured-nation clauses which bound
the colonies, the concessions given France had to
be extended to Austria, Denmark, Norway, Sweden, Spain,
and Switzerland. Belgium and Holland, both low-tariff
countries, received many of the same concessions, and
in the same year (1910) a special convention was made
with Italy. All the latter negotiations were
carried on direct between the Canadian Government and
the foreign consuls-general in Canada. In the
agreement with Italy the parties were termed
’the Royal Consul of Italy for Canada, representing
the government of the Kingdom of Italy, and the Minister
of Finance of Canada, representing His Excellency the
Governor-General acting in conjunction with the King’s
Privy Council for Canada.’
Meanwhile less friendly relations
had arisen with Germany. Angry at the action
of Canada in giving British goods a preference, Germany
in 1899 withdrew her minimum rates on Canadian products,
imposing the much higher general rates. The
Laurier Government protested that the British preference
was a family affair, and that so long as Germany was
given the same rates as other foreign countries she
had no excuse for retaliation. But this soft
answer did not turn away Teutonic wrath; so in 1903
Canada retorted in kind, by levying a surtax of one-third
on German goods. The war of tariffs lasted seven
years. While it hampered the trade of both countries,
German exports were much the hardest hit. Germany
took the initiative in seeking a truce, and in 1910
an agreement was reached between Mr Fielding and the
German consul-general. Germany dropped her protest
against the British preference, and gave the Dominion
the minimum rates on the most important dutiable
exports in return for, not the intermediate, but the
general tariff rates. So ended one of the few
instances of successful retaliation in all the chequered
annals of tariff history.
Secondly, as to men. This was
the issue with Asiatic powers. The opposition
to Asiatic immigration, so strong in Australia and
South Africa as well as in the United States, prevailed
in Western Canada. Working men demanded protection
against the too cheap and too efficient labour
of the Asiatic as validly as manufacturers objected
to the importation of the products of European ‘pauper
labour.’ Stronger, perhaps, was the cry
for a White Canada based on the difficulty of assimilation
and the danger to national unity of huge colonies
of Asiatics in the thinly peopled province beyond the
mountains.
Chinese navvies first came to Canada
to aid in building the government sections of the
Canadian Pacific Railway. An immediate outcry
followed, and in 1885 a head-tax of $50 was imposed
on all Chinese immigrants not of the official, merchant,
or scholar classes. During the nineties slightly
over two thousand a year paid the price of admission
to the Promised Land. Then growing prosperity
attracted greater swarms. Doubling the tax in
1901 only slightly checked the flow, but when it was
raised to $500 in 1904 the number willing to pay the
impost next year fell to eight. But higher wages,
or the chance of slipping over the United States border,
soon urged many to face even this barrier, and the
number paying head-tax rose to sixteen hundred (1910)
and later to seven thousand (1913). These rising
numbers led British Columbia to demand total exclusion;
but, thanks to the diffusion of the Chinese throughout
the Dominion, their lack of assertiveness and their
employment for the most part in industries which did
not compete with union men or the smaller merchants,
the agitation did not reach great proportions.
It was otherwise with the newcomers
from Japan. Their competition was more serious.
Aggressive and enterprising, filled with a due sense
of the greatness of Japan, aspiring to not merely
menial but controlling posts, they took firmer root
in the country than did the migratory Chinaman.
At the same time Japan’s rising power, her obvious
sensitiveness, and her alliance with Great Britain
made it expedient to treat her subjects more
warily than those of quiescent China. There
was practically no Japanese immigration until 1904-5,
when three hundred entered. In 1905 the Dominion
Government decided to adhere to the Anglo-Japanese
treaty in order to secure favourable terms in Japan’s
market. A clause of this treaty provided for
the free entrance of each country’s subjects
into the other country. When asked by the colonial
secretary whether they wished to reserve the right
to restrict immigration, as Queensland had done, the
Dominion authorities declared that they would accept
the treaty as it stood, relying upon semi-official
Japanese assurances of willingness to stop the flow
in Japan itself. Then suddenly, in 1906 and
1907, a large influx began, amounting to seven thousand
in a single year. This immigration, which was
prompted by Canadian mining and railway companies acting
in co-operation with Japanese societies, came via
the Hawaiian Islands. Alarm rose rapidly in British
Columbia, and was encouraged by agitators from the
United States. The climax came in September 1907,
when mobs attacked first the Chinese and later the
Japanese quarters in Vancouver, doing much damage
for a time, but being at last routed by Banzai-shouting
bands of angry Japanese. The Dominion Government
at once expressed its regret and in due time compensated
the sufferers from the riot. To solve the larger
question, Mr Lemieux was sent to Japan as a special
envoy. Cordially supported by the British ambassador
at Tokio, he succeeded in reaching a very satisfactory
agreement. The Japanese Government itself agreed
to restrict immigration direct from Japan, and to
raise no objection to Canadian prohibition of immigration
by way of Hawaii. This method was much more
acceptable to Japan’s pride than direct Canadian
restrictions would have been, and proved equally effective,
as the number of Japanese entering Canada averaged
only six hundred in the following years. The
Dominion Government’s course was open to criticism
in some points, but its earnest endeavour to safeguard
imperial as well as national interests, and the success
of Mr Lemieux’s diplomacy, were indications
that the Dominion was rising to the demands of its
new international position. Incidentally it
was the Government’s unwillingness to agree
to complete Japanese exclusion that in 1908 brought
the loss of every seat, save one, in British Columbia.
After the Alaskan boundary had been
settled, no critical issue arose between the two North
American democracies for several years. There
were still questions outstanding which in earlier days
would have given opportunity for tail-twisting or
eagle-plucking politicians to make trouble, but in
the new era of neighbourliness which now dawned they
were settled amicably or allowed to fall into blessed
oblivion.
A remarkable change in the spirit
in which the two peoples regarded each other came
about in this period. The abandonment by the
United States of its traditional policy of isolation,
its occupation of the Philippines, its policy of the
open door for China, its participation in the Morocco
dispute, effected a wonderful transformation in the
American attitude towards questions of foreign policy
and compelled a diplomacy more responsible and with
more of give and take. This led to incidents such
as that in Manila Bay, when a British admiral lined
up alongside the American fleet against a threatening
German squadron which made it clear that
Great Britain was the one trustworthy friend the United
States possessed. The steady growth of democratic
feeling in Britain, her daring experiments in
social betterment, her sympathetic treatment of the
Irish and South African questions, increased the friendliness
and the interest which the majority of Americans felt
at bottom for what was their motherland. Canada’s
prosperity awakened respectful interest. A country
which fifty or a hundred thousand good Americans every
year preferred to their own must be more than the
negligible northern fringe it once was thought to
be.
Canada reciprocated this more friendly
feeling. Prosperity mended her querulous mood
and made her too busy to remember the grievances of
earlier days. Her international horizon, too,
had widened; the United States was no longer the sole
foreign power with which she had to deal, though still
the most important. Yet this friendlier feeling
did not lead to a general desire for freer trade relations.
Quite the contrary; confident in her own newly realized
resources and in the possibility of finding markets
elsewhere, dominated by protectionist sentiment and
by the growing cities, Canada became on the whole
indifferent to what had once appeared an essential
goal. In Sir Wilfrid Laurier’s phrase,
the pilgrimages from Ottawa to Washington had ceased:
the pilgrimages must come, if at all, from Washington
to Ottawa.
Washington did come to Ottawa.
Notable was the visit of Secretary Root in 1907,
to discuss outstanding issues. Notable too, in
another direction, was the increased interest of the
British ambassador at Washington in Canadian affairs.
This was particularly true of Mr Bryce, who made
it a point to visit Ottawa every year of his term,
and declared that he was really more the Canadian
than the British ambassador. His skilful diplomacy
and his intimate knowledge of American politics served
Canada in good stead, and quieted the demand which
had frequently been voiced for a separate Canadian
representative at Washington.
Among the fruits of the new friendliness
and the more direct diplomatic discussion was the
settlement of two long-standing fishery disputes.
The much discussed Convention of 1818, in respect to
the Atlantic fisheries, was referred to the Hague
Tribunal in 1910, where it was finally set at rest.
The controversy as to fur-sealing on the Pacific
was settled by international agreement in 1911.
Less success was met in dealing with the fisheries
of the Great Lakes. A comprehensive treaty
for the protection and development of these fisheries,
drawn up in 1908, was not ratified because of the opposition
of some private interests in the United States.
The most significant achievement of
these years, however, was a broad provision for the
settlement of all disputes as to boundary waters.
The pressure for the use of boundary rivers for the
development of power, with all the difficult questions
arising as to division of the power or obstruction
to navigation, made necessary such a provision.
In accordance with a suggestion from the United States
a temporary Waterways Commission was set up (1905);
and in 1910 a treaty was ratified providing for a
permanent International Joint Commission, to consist
of three Canadians and three Americans. The treaty
provided, further, that any matter whatever in dispute
between the two countries, quite aside from boundary-water
issues, might be referred to the commission for settlement,
with the consent on the one hand of the United States
Senate, and on the other of the Governor-General in
Council the Dominion Cabinet. Quietly,
with little public discussion, the two countries concerned
thus took one of the most advanced steps yet made
towards the peaceful settlement of all possible
sources of conflict.
The revival of the tariff issue was
the most spectacular and most important episode in
the new relationship. The revival started in
the Republic. For some years a steadily growing
agitation in favour of reciprocity with Canada had
been carried on in the New England and Northwest states.
Nothing might have come of the agitation, however,
had not the Payne-Aldrich tariff of 1909 compelled
official negotiation and opened up the whole broad
issue. Under that tariff the system of maximum
and minimum schedules was adopted, the maximum designed
to serve as a club to compel other nations to yield
their lowest rates. The president was directed
to enforce these higher duties against all countries
which had not agreed by April 1910 to grant the concessions
demanded. The proposal partook of the highwayman’s
methods and ethics even more than is usual in protectionist
warfare; and it was with wry faces that one by one
the nations with maximum and minimum tariffs consented
to give the United States their lower rates.
France and Germany were the last of European nations
to accept. Canada alone remained.
It was admitted that the preference granted other
parts of the Empire did not constitute discrimination
against the United States, but it was contended that
the concessions made to France should be given to
the United States.
Canada resented this demand, in view
of the fact that the minimum tariff of the United
States stood much higher than the maximum of Canada,
and it was proposed to retaliate by a surtax on American
goods. In the United States there was wide sympathy
with this attitude; but under the act the president
had no option but to enforce the higher duties if
the concessions were not given. Fortunately he
was left to decide as to the adequacy of such concessions,
and this made agreement possible at the eleventh hour.
President Taft proposed a conference at Albany; the
Dominion Government accepted, and an agreement was
reached on the 30th of March, the last day of grace
but one. Canada conceded to the United States
its intermediate rates on a few articles of minor
importance china-ware, window-glass, feathers,
nuts, prunes, and other goods and the United
States accepted these as equivalent to the French
concessions. Then, to complete the comedy, Canada
at once made these lower rates part of its general
tariff, applying to any country, so that the United
States in the end was where it started enjoying
no special concessions whatever. Canada had
gone through the motions of making a concession, and
that sufficed.
This agreement, however, was only
the beginning. President Taft, who recognized
too late that he had antagonized the growing low-tariff
sentiment in the United States by his support of the
Payne-Aldrich tariff, decided to attempt a stroke
for freer trade. He proposed a broad revision
of trade relations with Canada. In negotiations
which began at Ottawa and were concluded at Washington
in January 1911, an agreement for a wide measure of
reciprocal free trade was effected. It was nearly
as broad as the treaty of 1854. Grain, fruit
and vegetables, dairy products, live stock, fish,
hewn lumber and sawn boards, and many minerals were
put on the free list. Meats, flour, coal and
other articles free in the earlier agreement were subjected
to reduced rates, a limited number of manufactured
articles were included, some of them Canadian and
some of them American specialties. The agreement
was to be effected, not by treaty but by concurrent
legislation for an indefinite period. The
Canadian Government announced that the same terms
would be granted all parts of the British Empire.
After the cabinets, the legislatures.
President Taft had great difficulty in securing the
consent of Congress. Farmers and fishermen,
stand-pat Republicans and anti-administration insurgents,
opposed this sudden reversal of a traditional policy.
Only by the aid of Democratic votes in a special
session of Congress was the measure adopted, late in
July. Meanwhile the Opposition in the Canadian
parliament, after some initial hesitation, had attacked
it with growing force. They resorted to the
obstruction which the Liberals had practised in 1896,
and compelled the Government to appeal to the country,
a week after Congress had accepted the agreement.
After parliament, the people.
Apparently the Government anticipated that the bargain
would be welcomed by nearly all Canadians. That
expectation was not without warrant. It was such
a treaty as Canada had sought time and again during
the last fifty years, and such as both parties would
have accepted without question twenty years before.
Every important leader of the Conservative party was
on record as favouring such an arrangement.
Yet it was received first with hesitation, then more
and more freely denounced, and finally overwhelmed.
On the economic issues concerned the
advocates of the agreement apparently had a good case.
The farmer, the miner, the fisherman stood to gain
from it, not so notably as they would have done twenty
years before, but yet undoubtedly to gain. It
was contended that the United States was itself a
rival producer of most of the commodities in question,
and that Canada would be exposed to the competition
of the British Dominions and the most-favoured nations.
These arguments had force, but could not balance
the advantages of the arrangement, especially to the
western farmer. That this gain would accrue and
a large trade north and south be created, to the destruction
of trade east and west, was in fact made by the opponents
of the treaty the chief corner-stone of their economic
argument. It was held, too, that the raw products
of farm and sea and forest and mine ought not to be
shipped out of the country, but ought to be kept at
home as the basis of manufacturing industries.
And though the arrangement scarcely touched the manufacturers,
the thin end of the wedge argument had much weight
with them and their workmen. It would lead,
they thought, to a still wider measure of trade freedom
which would expose them to the competition of American
manufacturers.
But it was the political aspect of
the pact that the Conservatives most emphasized.
Once more, as in 1891, they declared Canadian nationality
and British connection to be at stake. Reciprocity
would prove the first long step towards annexation.
Such was the intention, they urged, of its American
upholders, a claim given some colour by President
Taft’s maladroit ‘parting of the ways’
speech and by Speaker Clark’s misplacedly humorous
remark, ’we are preparing to annex Canada.’
And while in Canada there might be as yet few annexationists,
the tendency of a vast and intimate trade north and
south would be to make many. Where the treasure
was, there would the heart be also. The movement
for imperial preferential trade, then strong in the
United Kingdom, would be for ever defeated if the
American offer should be accepted. Canada must
not sell her birthright for a mess of Yankee pottage.
The advocates of reciprocity denounced
these arguments as the sheerest buncombe. Annexation
sentiment in the United States they declared
to be rapidly disappearing, and in any case it was
Canada’s views, not those of the United States,
that mattered. Reciprocity from 1854 to 1866
had killed, not fostered, annexation sentiment in Canada.
And, if the doubling and trebling of imports from the
United States in recent years had not kept national
and imperial sentiment from rising to flood-tide,
why now should an increase of exports breed disloyalty?
Canadian financiers and railway operators were entering
into ever closer relations with the United States;
why should the farmer be denied the same right?
The reciprocity proposed in 1911, unlike the programme
of twenty years earlier, did not involve discrimination
against Great Britain, but in fact went along with
a still greater preference to the mother country.
The claim that reciprocity would kill imperial preference
was meaningless in face of this actual fact.
Moreover, the British tariff reformers proclaimed their
intention, if Mr Chamberlain’s policy prevailed,
of making reciprocity treaties with foreign countries
as well as preferential arrangements with the Dominions,
so why should not Canada exercise the same freedom?
But elections are not won merely by
such debate. The energy with which they
are fought, or the weight of the interests vitally
concerned, may prove more decisive than argument.
And in this contest the Opposition had the far more
effective fighting force and made the far stronger
appeal. Mr Borden’s followers fought with
the eager enthusiasm which is bred of long exclusion
from office, while the ministerialists save
only the veteran prime minister himself and a small
band of his supporters fought feebly, as
if dulled by the satiety which comes of long possession
of the loaves and fishes. Outside the party bounds
the situation was the same. The western farmers
were the only organized and articulate body on the
side of reciprocity, while opposed to it were the
powerful and well-equipped forces of the manufacturers
and the closely allied transportation and financial
interests. Through the press and from a thousand
platforms these forces appealed to the dominant beliefs
and feelings of the people. Quite effective
was the appeal founded on the doctrine of protection.
In twenty years Canada had become a city-dominated
land, and the average city-dweller had come to believe
that his interests were bound up with protection a
belief not unnatural in the absence for a decade
of any radical discussion of the issue, and not to
be overcome at the eleventh hour. But the patriotic
appeal was still more effective. Here was a
chance to express the accumulated resentment of half
a century against the unneighbourly policy of the
United States, now suddenly reversed. The chance
could safely be seized, for Canada was prosperous
beyond all precedent. ’Let well enough
alone’ was in itself a vote-compelling cry.
In fact, ’Laurier prosperity’ proved
its own Nemesis. Jeshurun Ontario, having waxed
fat, kicked. An American philosopher, Artemus
Ward, has recorded that his patriotism was so worked
up during the Civil War that he consented to send
all his wife’s relations to the front.
Many an Ontario patriot in 1911 was prepared to sacrifice
the interests of his fellow-Canadians to prove his
independence of the United States. And in Quebec
the working arrangement between the Conservatives
and Mr Henri Bourassa and his party told heavily against
the Government.
The result of the elections, which
were held on the 21st of September, was the overwhelming
defeat of Sir Wilfrid Laurier’s Ministry.
In Ontario the Liberals saved only thirteen seats
out of eighty-six. In the rest of the
country they had a majority, but not sufficient to
reduce substantially this adverse Ontario vote.
The complete returns gave 133 Conservatives to 88
Liberals. As usual, the popular vote was more
equally divided than the parliamentary seats, for the
Liberals secured 625,000 and the Conservatives 669,000
votes. The Liberal majority of only 5000 in
Quebec, 3000 in the maritime provinces, and 20,000
in the prairie provinces was overcome by the Conservative
majority of 63,000 in Ontario and 9000 in British
Columbia. A fortnight later Sir Wilfrid Laurier
tendered his resignation to the governor-general and
Mr Borden formed his Government.