Dress as an Expression of the Pecuniary Culture
It will in place, by way of illustration,
to show in some detail how the economic principles
so far set forth apply to everyday facts in some one
direction of the life process. For this purpose
no line of consumption affords a more apt illustration
than expenditure on dress. It is especially the
rule of the conspicuous waste of goods that finds
expression in dress, although the other, related principles
of pecuniary repute are also exemplified in the same
contrivances. Other methods of putting one’s
pecuniary standing in evidence serve their end effectually,
and other methods are in vogue always and everywhere;
but expenditure on dress has this advantage over most
other methods, that our apparel is always in evidence
and affords an indication of our pecuniary standing
to all observers at the first glance. It is also
true that admitted expenditure for display is more
obviously present, and is, perhaps, more universally
practiced in the matter of dress than in any other
line of consumption. No one finds difficulty in
assenting to the commonplace that the greater part
of the expenditure incurred by all classes for apparel
is incurred for the sake of a respectable appearance
rather than for the protection of the person.
And probably at no other point is the sense of shabbiness
so keenly felt as it is if we fall short of the standard
set by social usage in this matter of dress. It
is true of dress in even a higher degree than of most
other items of consumption, that people will undergo
a very considerable degree of privation in the comforts
or the necessaries of life in order to afford what
is considered a decent amount of wasteful consumption;
so that it is by no means an uncommon occurrence,
in an inclement climate, for people to go ill clad
in order to appear well dressed. And the commercial
value of the goods used for clotting in any modern
community is made up to a much larger extent of the
fashionableness, the reputability of the goods than
of the mechanical service which they render in clothing
the person of the wearer. The need of dress is
eminently a “higher” or spiritual need.
This spiritual need of dress is not
wholly, nor even chiefly, a naïve propensity for display
of expenditure. The law of conspicuous waste
guides consumption in apparel, as in other things,
chiefly at the second remove, by shaping the canons
of taste and decency. In the common run of cases
the conscious motive of the wearer or purchaser of
conspicuously wasteful apparel is the need of conforming
to established usage, and of living up to the accredited
standard of taste and reputability. It is not
only that one must be guided by the code of proprieties
in dress in order to avoid the mortification that
comes of unfavorable notice and comment, though that
motive in itself counts for a great deal; but besides
that, the requirement of expensiveness is so ingrained
into our habits of thought in matters of dress that
any other than expensive apparel is instinctively
odious to us. Without reflection or analysis,
we feel that what is inexpensive is unworthy.
“A cheap coat makes a cheap man.”
“Cheap and nasty” is recognized to hold
true in dress with even less mitigation than in other
lines of consumption. On the ground both of taste
and of serviceability, an inexpensive article of apparel
is held to be inferior, under the maxim “cheap
and nasty.” We find things beautiful, as
well as serviceable, somewhat in proportion as they
are costly. With few and inconsequential exceptions,
we all find a costly hand-wrought article of apparel
much preferable, in point of beauty and of serviceability,
to a less expensive imitation of it, however cleverly
the spurious article may imitate the costly original;
and what offends our sensibilities in the spurious
article is not that it falls short in form or color,
or, indeed, in visual effect in any way. The
offensive object may be so close an imitation as to
defy any but the closest scrutiny; and yet so soon
as the counterfeit is detected, its aesthetic value,
and its commercial value as well, declines precipitately.
Not only that, but it may be asserted with but small
risk of contradiction that the aesthetic value of a
detected counterfeit in dress declines somewhat in
the same proportion as the counterfeit is cheaper
than its original. It loses caste aesthetically
because it falls to a lower pecuniary grade.
But the function of dress as an evidence
of ability to pay does not end with simply showing
that the wearer consumes valuable goods in excess of
what is required for physical comfort. Simple
conspicuous waste of goods is effective and gratifying
as far as it goes; it is good prima facie evidence
of pecuniary success, and consequently prima facie
evidence of social worth. But dress has subtler
and more far-reaching possibilities than this crude,
first-hand evidence of wasteful consumption only.
If, in addition to showing that the wearer can afford
to consume freely and uneconomically, it can also
be shown in the same stroke that he or she is not
under the necessity of earning a livelihood, the evidence
of social worth is enhanced in a very considerable
degree. Our dress, therefore, in order to serve
its purpose effectually, should not only he expensive,
but it should also make plain to all observers that
the wearer is not engaged in any kind of productive
labor. In the evolutionary process by which our
system of dress has been elaborated into its present
admirably perfect adaptation to its purpose, this
subsidiary line of evidence has received due attention.
A detailed examination of what passes in popular apprehension
for elegant apparel will show that it is contrived
at every point to convey the impression that the wearer
does not habitually put forth any useful effort.
It goes without saying that no apparel can be considered
elegant, or even decent, if it shows the effect of
manual labor on the part of the wearer, in the way
of soil or wear. The pleasing effect of neat and
spotless garments is chiefly, if not altogether, due
to their carrying the suggestion of leisure-exemption
from personal contact with industrial processes of
any kind. Much of the charm that invests the
patent-leather shoe, the stainless linen, the lustrous
cylindrical hat, and the walking-stick, which so greatly
enhance the native dignity of a gentleman, comes of
their pointedly suggesting that the wearer cannot
when so attired bear a hand in any employment that
is directly and immediately of any human use.
Elegant dress serves its purpose of elegance not only
in that it is expensive, but also because it is the
insignia of leisure. It not only shows that the
wearer is able to consume a relatively large value,
but it argues at the same time that he consumes without
producing.
The dress of women goes even farther
than that of men in the way of demonstrating the wearer’s
abstinence from productive employment. It needs
no argument to enforce the generalization that the
more elegant styles of feminine bonnets go even farther
towards making work impossible than does the man’s
high hat. The woman’s shoe adds the so-called
French heel to the evidence of enforced leisure afforded
by its polish; because this high heel obviously makes
any, even the simplest and most necessary manual work
extremely difficult. The like is true even in
a higher degree of the skirt and the rest of the drapery
which characterizes woman’s dress. The substantial
reason for our tenacious attachment to the skirt is
just this; it is expensive and it hampers the wearer
at every turn and incapacitates her for all useful
exertion. The like is true of the feminine custom
of wearing the hair excessively long.
But the woman’s apparel not
only goes beyond that of the modern man in the degree
in which it argues exemption from labor; it also adds
a peculiar and highly characteristic feature which
differs in kind from anything habitually practiced
by the men. This feature is the class of contrivances
of which the corset is the typical example. The
corset is, in economic theory, substantially a mutilation,
undergone for the purpose of lowering the subject’s
vitality and rendering her permanently and obviously
unfit for work. It is true, the corset impairs
the personal attractions of the wearer, but the loss
suffered on that score is offset by the gain in reputability
which comes of her visibly increased expensiveness
and infirmity. It may broadly be set down that
the womanliness of woman’s apparel resolves itself,
in point of substantial fact, into the more effective
hindrance to useful exertion offered by the garments
peculiar to women. This difference between masculine
and feminine apparel is here simply pointed out as
a characteristic feature. The ground of its occurrence
will be discussed presently.
So far, then, we have, as the great
and dominant norm of dress, the broad principle of
conspicuous waste. Subsidiary to this principle,
and as a corollary under it, we get as a second norm
the principle of conspicuous leisure. In dress
construction this norm works out in the shape of divers
contrivances going to show that the wearer does not
and, as far as it may conveniently be shown, can not
engage in productive labor. Beyond these two
principles there is a third of scarcely less constraining
force, which will occur to any one who reflects at
all on the subject. Dress must not only be conspicuously
expensive and inconvenient, it must at the same time
be up to date. No explanation at all satisfactory
has hitherto been offered of the phenomenon of changing
fashions. The imperative requirement of dressing
in the latest accredited manner, as well as the fact
that this accredited fashion constantly changes from
season to season, is sufficiently familiar to every
one, but the theory of this flux and change has not
been worked out. We may of course say, with perfect
consistency and truthfulness, that this principle
of novelty is another corollary under the law of conspicuous
waste. Obviously, if each garment is permitted
to serve for but a brief term, and if none of last
season’s apparel is carried over and made further
use of during the present season, the wasteful expenditure
on dress is greatly increased. This is good as
far as it goes, but it is negative only. Pretty
much all that this consideration warrants us in saying
is that the norm of conspicuous waste exercises a
controlling surveillance in all matters of dress, so
that any change in the fashions must conspicuous waste
exercises a controlling surveillance in all matters
of dress, so that any change in the fashions must conform
to the requirement of wastefulness; it leaves unanswered
the question as to the motive for making and accepting
a change in the prevailing styles, and it also fails
to explain why conformity to a given style at a given
time is so imperatively necessary as we know it to
be.
For a creative principle, capable
of serving as motive to invention and innovation in
fashions, we shall have to go back to the primitive,
non-economic motive with which apparel originated the
motive of adornment. Without going into an extended
discussion of how and why this motive asserts itself
under the guidance of the law of expensiveness, it
may be stated broadly that each successive innovation
in the fashions is an effort to reach some form of
display which shall be more acceptable to our sense
of form and color or of effectiveness, than that which
it displaces. The changing styles are the expression
of a restless search for something which shall commend
itself to our aesthetic sense; but as each innovation
is subject to the selective action of the norm of
conspicuous waste, the range within which innovation
can take place is somewhat restricted. The innovation
must not only be more beautiful, or perhaps oftener
less offensive, than that which it displaces, but it
must also come up to the accepted standard of expensiveness.
It would seem at first sight that
the result of such an unremitting struggle to attain
the beautiful in dress should be a gradual approach
to artistic perfection. We might naturally expect
that the fashions should show a well-marked trend
in the direction of some one or more types of apparel
eminently becoming to the human form; and we might
even feel that ge have substantial ground for the
hope that today, after all the ingenuity and effort
which have been spent on dress these many years, the
fashions should have achieved a relative perfection
and a relative stability, closely approximating to
a permanently tenable artistic ideal. But such
is not the case. It would be very hazardous indeed
to assert that the styles of today are intrinsically
more becoming than those of ten years ago, or than
those of twenty, or fifty, or one hundred years ago.
On the other hand, the assertion freely goes uncontradicted
that styles in vogue two thousand years ago are more
becoming than the most elaborate and painstaking constructions
of today.
The explanation of the fashions just
offered, then, does not fully explain, and we shall
have to look farther. It is well known that certain
relatively stable styles and types of costume have
been worked out in various parts of the world; as,
for instance, among the Japanese, Chinese, and other
Oriental nations; likewise among the Greeks, Romans,
and other Eastern peoples of antiquity so also, in
later times, among the peasants of nearly every country
of Europe. These national or popular costumes
are in most cases adjudged by competent critics to
be more becoming, more artistic, than the fluctuating
styles of modern civilized apparel. At the same
time they are also, at least usually, less obviously
wasteful; that is to say, other elements than that
of a display of expense are more readily detected
in their structure.
These relatively stable costumes are,
commonly, pretty strictly and narrowly localized,
and they vary by slight and systematic gradations
from place to place. They have in every case been
worked out by peoples or classes which are poorer
than we, and especially they belong in countries and
localities and times where the population, or at least
the class to which the costume in question belongs,
is relatively homogeneous, stable, and immobile.
That is to say, stable costumes which will bear the
test of time and perspective are worked out under
circumstances where the norm of conspicuous waste asserts
itself less imperatively than it does in the large
modern civilized cities, whose relatively mobile wealthy
population today sets the pace in matters of fashion.
The countries and classes which have in this way worked
out stable and artistic costumes have been so placed
that the pecuniary emulation among them has taken
the direction of a competition in conspicuous leisure
rather than in conspicuous consumption of goods.
So that it will hold true in a general way that fashions
are least stable and least becoming in those communities
where the principle of a conspicuous waste of goods
asserts itself most imperatively, as among ourselves.
All this points to an antagonism between expensiveness
and artistic apparel. In point of practical fact,
the norm of conspicuous waste is incompatible with
the requirement that dress should be beautiful or
becoming. And this antagonism offers an explanation
of that restless change in fashion which neither the
canon of expensiveness nor that of beauty alone can
account for.
The standard of reputability requires
that dress should show wasteful expenditure; but all
wastefulness is offensive to native taste. The
psychological law has already been pointed out that
all men and women perhaps even in a higher
degree abhor futility, whether of effort or of expenditure much
as Nature was once said to abhor a vacuum. But
the principle of conspicuous waste requires an obviously
futile expenditure; and the resulting conspicuous
expensiveness of dress is therefore intrinsically
ugly. Hence we find that in all innovations in
dress, each added or altered detail strives to avoid
condemnation by showing some ostensible purpose, at
the same time that the requirement of conspicuous
waste prevents the purposefulness of these innovations
from becoming anything more than a somewhat transparent
pretense. Even in its freest flights, fashion
rarely if ever gets away from a simulation of some
ostensible use. The ostensible usefulness of the
fashionable details of dress, however, is always so
transparent a make-believe, and their substantial
futility presently forces itself so baldly upon our
attention as to become unbearable, and then we take
refuge in a new style. But the new style must
conform to the requirement of reputable wastefulness
and futility. Its futility presently becomes as
odious as that of its predecessor; and the only remedy
which the law of waste allows us is to seek relief
in some new construction, equally futile and equally
untenable. Hence the essential ugliness and the
unceasing change of fashionable attire.
Having so explained the phenomenon
of shifting fashions, the next thing is to make the
explanation tally with everyday facts. Among these
everyday facts is the well-known liking which all men
have for the styles that are in vogue at any given
time. A new style comes into vogue and remains
in favor for a season, and, at least so long as it
is a novelty, people very generally find the new style
attractive. The prevailing fashion is felt to
be beautiful. This is due partly to the relief
it affords in being different from what went before
it, partly to its being reputable. As indicated
in the last chapter, the canon of reputability to
some extent shapes our tastes, so that under its guidance
anything will be accepted as becoming until its novelty
wears off, or until the warrant of reputability is
transferred to a new and novel structure serving the
same general purpose. That the alleged beauty,
or “loveliness,” of the styles in vogue
at any given time is transient and spurious only is
attested by the fact that none of the many shifting
fashions will bear the test of time. When seen
in the perspective of half-a-dozen years or more,
the best of our fashions strike us as grotesque, if
not unsightly. Our transient attachment to whatever
happens to be the latest rests on other than aesthetic
grounds, and lasts only until our abiding aesthetic
sense has had time to assert itself and reject this
latest indigestible contrivance.
The process of developing an aesthetic
nausea takes more or less time; the length of time
required in any given case being inversely as the
degree of intrinsic odiousness of the style in question.
This time relation between odiousness and instability
in fashions affords ground for the inference that
the more rapidly the styles succeed and displace one
another, the more offensive they are to sound taste.
The presumption, therefore, is that the farther the
community, especially the wealthy classes of the community,
develop in wealth and mobility and in the range of
their human contact, the more imperatively will the
law of conspicuous waste assert itself in matters
of dress, the more will the sense of beauty tend to
fall into abeyance or be overborne by the canon of
pecuniary reputability, the more rapidly will fashions
shift and change, and the more grotesque and intolerable
will be the varying styles that successively come
into vogue.
There remains at least one point in
this theory of dress yet to be discussed. Most
of what has been said applies to men’s attire
as well as to that of women; although in modern times
it applies at nearly all points with greater force
to that of women. But at one point the dress
of women differs substantially from that of men.
In woman’s dress there is obviously greater
insistence on such features as testify to the wearer’s
exemption from or incapacity for all vulgarly productive
employment. This characteristic of woman’s
apparel is of interest, not only as completing the
theory of dress, but also as confirming what has already
been said of the economic status of women, both in
the past and in the present.
As has been seen in the discussion
of woman’s status under the heads of Vicarious
Leisure and Vicarious Consumption, it has in the course
of economic development become the office of the woman
to consume vicariously for the head of the household;
and her apparel is contrived with this object in view.
It has come about that obviously productive labor
is in a peculiar degree derogatory to respectable women,
and therefore special pains should be taken in the
construction of women’s dress, to impress upon
the beholder the fact (often indeed a fiction) that
the wearer does not and can not habitually engage in
useful work. Propriety requires respectable women
to abstain more consistently from useful effort and
to make more of a show of leisure than the men of the
same social classes. It grates painfully on our
nerves to contemplate the necessity of any well-bred
woman’s earning a livelihood by useful work.
It is not “woman’s sphere.”
Her sphere is within the household, which she should
“beautify,” and of which she should be
the “chief ornament.” The male head
of the household is not currently spoken of as its
ornament. This feature taken in conjunction with
the other fact that propriety requires more unremitting
attention to expensive display in the dress and other
paraphernalia of women, goes to enforce the view already
implied in what has gone before. By virtue of
its descent from a patriarchal past, our social system
makes it the woman’s function in an especial
degree to put in evidence her household’s ability
to pay. According to the modern civilized scheme
of life, the good name of the household to which she
belongs should be the special care of the woman; and
the system of honorific expenditure and conspicuous
leisure by which this good name is chiefly sustained
is therefore the woman’s sphere. In the
ideal scheme, as it tends to realize itself in the
life of the higher pecuniary classes, this attention
to conspicuous waste of substance and effort should
normally be the sole economic function of the woman.
At the stage of economic development
at which the women were still in the full sense the
property of the men, the performance of conspicuous
leisure and consumption came to be part of the services
required of them. The women being not their own
masters, obvious expenditure and leisure on their
part would redound to the credit of their master rather
than to their own credit; and therefore the more expensive
and the more obviously unproductive the women of the
household are, the more creditable and more effective
for the purpose of reputability of the household or
its head will their life be. So much so that the
women have been required not only to afford evidence
of a life of leisure, but even to disable themselves
for useful activity.
It is at this point that the dress
of men falls short of that of women, and for sufficient
reason. Conspicuous waste and conspicuous leisure
are reputable because they are evidence of pecuniary
strength; pecuniary strength is reputable or honorific
because, in the last analysis, it argues success and
superior force; therefore the evidence of waste and
leisure put forth by any individual in his own behalf
cannot consistently take such a form or be carried
to such a pitch as to argue incapacity or marked discomfort
on his part; as the exhibition would in that case
show not superior force, but inferiority, and so defeat
its own purpose. So, then, wherever wasteful
expenditure and the show of abstention from effort
is normally, or on an average, carried to the extent
of showing obvious discomfort or voluntarily induced
physical disability. There the immediate inference
is that the individual in question does not perform
this wasteful expenditure and undergo this disability
for her own personal gain in pecuniary repute, but
in behalf of some one else to whom she stands in a
relation of economic dependence; a relation which
in the last analysis must, in economic theory, reduce
itself to a relation of servitude.
To apply this generalization to women’s
dress, and put the matter in concrete terms:
the high heel, the skirt, the impracticable bonnet,
the corset, and the general disregard of the wearer’s
comfort which is an obvious feature of all civilized
women’s apparel, are so many items of evidence
to the effect that in the modern civilized scheme of
life the woman is still, in theory, the economic dependent
of the man that, perhaps in a highly idealized
sense, she still is the man’s chattel. The
homely reason for all this conspicuous leisure and
attire on the part of women lies in the fact that
they are servants to whom, in the differentiation
of economic functions, has been delegated the office
of putting in evidence their master’s ability
to pay. There is a marked similarity in these
respects between the apparel of women and that of
domestic servants, especially liveried servants.
In both there is a very elaborate show of unnecessary
expensiveness, and in both cases there is also a notable
disregard of the physical comfort of the wearer.
But the attire of the lady goes farther in its elaborate
insistence on the idleness, if not on the physical
infirmity of the wearer, than does that of the domestic.
And this is as it should be; for in theory, according
to the ideal scheme of the pecuniary culture, the lady
of the house is the chief menial of the household.
Besides servants, currently recognized
as such, there is at least one other class of persons
whose garb assimilates them to the class of servants
and shows many of the features that go to make up the
womanliness of woman’s dress. This is the
priestly class. Priestly vestments show, in accentuated
form, all the features that have been shown to be
evidence of a servile status and a vicarious life.
Even more strikingly than the everyday habit of the
priest, the vestments, properly so called, are ornate,
grotesque, inconvenient, and, at least ostensibly,
comfortless to the point of distress. The priest
is at the same time expected to refrain from useful
effort and, when before the public eye, to present
an impassively disconsolate countenance, very much
after the manner of a well-trained domestic servant.
The shaven face of the priest is a further item to
the same effect. This assimilation of the priestly
class to the class of body servants, in demeanor and
apparel, is due to the similarity of the two classes
as regards economic function. In economic theory,
the priest is a body servant, constructively in attendance
upon the person of the divinity whose livery he wears.
His livery is of a very expensive character, as it
should be in order to set forth in a beseeming manner
the dignity of his exalted master; but it is contrived
to show that the wearing of it contributes little
or nothing to the physical comfort of the wearer,
for it is an item of vicarious consumption, and the
repute which accrues from its consumption is to be
imputed to the absent master, not to the servant.
The line of demarcation between the
dress of women, priests, and servants, on the one
hand, and of men, on the other hand, is not always
consistently observed in practice, but it will scarcely
be disputed that it is always present in a more or
less definite way in the popular habits of thought.
There are of course also free men, and not a few of
them, who, in their blind zeal for faultless reputable
attire, transgress the theoretical line between man’s
and woman’s dress, to the extent of arraying
themselves in apparel that is obviously designed to
vex the mortal frame; but everyone recognizes without
hesitation that such apparel for men is a departure
from the normal. We are in the habit of saying
that such dress is “effeminate”; and one
sometimes hears the remark that such or such an exquisitely
attired gentleman is as well dressed as a footman.
Certain apparent discrepancies under
this theory of dress merit a more detailed examination,
especially as they mark a more or less evident trend
in the later and maturer development of dress.
The vogue of the corset offers an apparent exception
from the rule of which it has here been cited as an
illustration. A closer examination, however, will
show that this apparent exception is really a verification
of the rule that the vogue of any given element or
feature in dress rests on its utility as an evidence
of pecuniary standing. It is well known that in
the industrially more advanced communities the corset
is employed only within certain fairly well defined
social strata. The women of the poorer classes,
especially of the rural population, do not habitually
use it, except as a holiday luxury. Among these
classes the women have to work hard, and it avails
them little in the way of a pretense of leisure to
so crucify the flesh in everyday life. The holiday
use of the contrivance is due to imitation of a higher-class
canon of decency. Upwards from this low level
of indigence and manual labor, the corset was until
within a generation or two nearly indispensable to
a socially blameless standing for all women, including
the wealthiest and most reputable. This rule
held so long as there still was no large class of
people wealthy enough to be above the imputation of
any necessity for manual labor and at the same time
large enough to form a self-sufficient, isolated social
body whose mass would afford a foundation for special
rules of conduct within the class, enforced by the
current opinion of the class alone. But now there
has grown up a large enough leisure class possessed
of such wealth that any aspersion on the score of
enforced manual employment would be idle and harmless
calumny; and the corset has therefore in large measure
fallen into disuse within this class. The exceptions
under this rule of exemption from the corset are more
apparent than real. They are the wealthy classes
of countries with a lower industrial structure nearer
the archaic, quasi-industrial type together
with the later accessions of the wealthy classes in
the more advanced industrial communities. The
latter have not yet had time to divest themselves of
the plebeian canons of taste and of reputability carried
over from their former, lower pecuniary grade.
Such survival of the corset is not infrequent among
the higher social classes of those American cities,
for instance, which have recently and rapidly risen
into opulence. If the word be used as a technical
term, without any odious implication, it may be said
that the corset persists in great measure through
the period of snobbery the interval of
uncertainty and of transition from a lower to the upper
levels of pecuniary culture. That is to say, in
all countries which have inherited the corset it continues
in use wherever and so long as it serves its purpose
as an evidence of honorific leisure by arguing physical
disability in the wearer. The same rule of course
applies to other mutilations and contrivances for
decreasing the visible efficiency of the individual.
Something similar should hold true
with respect to divers items of conspicuous consumption,
and indeed something of the kind does seem to hold
to a slight degree of sundry features of dress, especially
if such features involve a marked discomfort or appearance
of discomfort to the wearer. During the past
one hundred years there is a tendency perceptible,
in the development of men’s dress especially,
to discontinue methods of expenditure and the use
of symbols of leisure which must have been irksome,
which may have served a good purpose in their time,
but the continuation of which among the upper classes
today would be a work of supererogation; as, for instance,
the use of powdered wigs and of gold lace, and the
practice of constantly shaving the face. There
has of late years been some slight recrudescence of
the shaven face in polite society, but this is probably
a transient and unadvised mimicry of the fashion imposed
upon body servants, and it may fairly be expected
to go the way of the powdered wig of our grandfathers.
These indices and others which resemble
them in point of the boldness with which they point
out to all observers the habitual uselessness of those
persons who employ them, have been replaced by other,
more dedicate methods of expressing the same fact;
methods which are no less evident to the trained eyes
of that smaller, select circle whose good opinion
is chiefly sought. The earlier and cruder method
of advertisement held its ground so long as the public
to which the exhibitor had to appeal comprised large
portions of the community who were not trained to
detect delicate variations in the evidences of wealth
and leisure. The method of advertisement undergoes
a refinement when a sufficiently large wealthy class
has developed, who have the leisure for acquiring
skill in interpreting the subtler signs of expenditure.
“Loud” dress becomes offensive to people
of taste, as evincing an undue desire to reach and
impress the untrained sensibilities of the vulgar.
To the individual of high breeding, it is only the
more honorific esteem accorded by the cultivated sense
of the members of his own high class that is of material
consequence. Since the wealthy leisure class
has grown so large, or the contact of the leisure-class
individual with members of his own class has grown
so wide, as to constitute a human environment sufficient
for the honorific purpose, there arises a tendency
to exclude the baser elements of the population from
the scheme even as spectators whose applause or mortification
should be sought. The result of all this is a
refinement of methods, a resort to subtler contrivances,
and a spiritualization of the scheme of symbolism
in dress. And as this upper leisure class sets
the pace in all matters of decency, the result for
the rest of society also is a gradual amelioration
of the scheme of dress. As the community advances
in wealth and culture, the ability to pay is put in
evidence by means which require a progressively nicer
discrimination in the beholder. This nicer discrimination
between advertising media is in fact a very large
element of the higher pecuniary culture.