For any social movement or development
there must be a maximum limit beyond which it cannot
proceed. That civilization which does not advance
must decline, and so, when the maximum of development
has been reached in any given direction, society must
either retrograde or change the direction of its advance.
There are many families of men that have failed,
in the critical period of their economic evolution,
to effect a change in direction, and were forced to
fall back. Vanquished at the moment of their
maximum, they have dropped out of the whirl of the
world. There was no room for them. Stronger
competitors have taken their places, and they have
either rotted into oblivion or remain to be crushed
under the iron heel of the dominant races in as remorseless
a struggle as the world has yet witnessed. But
in this struggle fair women and chivalrous men will
play no part. Types and ideals have changed.
Helens and Launcelots are anachronisms. Blows
will be given and taken, and men fight and die, but
not for faiths and altars. Shrines will be desecrated,
but they will be the shrines, not of temples, but
market-places. Prophets will arise, but they
will be the prophets of prices and products.
Battles will be waged, not for honor and glory, nor
for thrones and sceptres, but for dollars and cents
and for marts and exchanges. Brain and not brawn
will endure, and the captains of war will be commanded
by the captains of industry. In short, it will
be a contest for the mastery of the world’s
commerce and for industrial supremacy.
It is more significant, this struggle
into which we have plunged, for the fact that it is
the first struggle to involve the globe. No general
movement of man has been so wide-spreading, so far-reaching.
Quite local was the supremacy of any ancient people;
likewise the rise to empire of Macedonia and Rome,
the waves of Arabian valor and fanaticism, and the
mediaeval crusades to the Holy Sepulchre. But
since those times the planet has undergone a unique
shrinkage.
The world of Homer, limited by the
coast-lines of the Mediterranean and Black seas, was
a far vaster world than ours of today, which we weigh,
measure, and compute as accurately and as easily as
if it were a child’s play-ball. Steam
has made its parts accessible and drawn them closer
together. The telegraph annihilates space and
time. Each morning, every part knows what every
other part is thinking, contemplating, or doing.
A discovery in a German laboratory is being demonstrated
in San Francisco within twenty-four hours. A
book written in South Africa is published by simultaneous
copyright in every English-speaking country, and on
the day following is in the hands of the translators.
The death of an obscure missionary in China, or of
a whiskey-smuggler in the South Seas, is served, the
world over, with the morning toast. The wheat
output of Argentine or the gold of Klondike are known
wherever men meet and trade. Shrinkage, or centralization,
has become such that the humblest clerk in any metropolis
may place his hand on the pulse of the world.
The planet has indeed grown very small; and because
of this, no vital movement can remain in the clime
or country where it takes its rise.
And so today the economic and industrial
impulse is world-wide. It is a matter of import
to every people. None may be careless of it.
To do so is to perish. It is become a battle,
the fruits of which are to the strong, and to none
but the strongest of the strong. As the movement
approaches its maximum, centralization accelerates
and competition grows keener and closer. The
competitor nations cannot all succeed. So long
as the movement continues its present direction, not
only will there not be room for all, but the room
that is will become less and less; and when the moment
of the maximum is at hand, there will be no room at
all. Capitalistic production will have overreached
itself, and a change of direction will then be inevitable.
Divers queries arise: What is
the maximum of commercial development the world can
sustain? How far can it be exploited? How
much capital is necessary? Can sufficient capital
be accumulated? A brief resume of the industrial
history of the last one hundred years or so will be
relevant at this stage of the discussion. Capitalistic
production, in its modern significance, was born of
the industrial revolution in England in the latter
half of the eighteenth century. The great inventions
of that period were both its father and its mother,
while, as Mr. Brooks Adams has shown, the looted treasure
of India was the potent midwife. Had there not
been an unwonted increase of capital, the impetus would
not have been given to invention, while even steam
might have languished for generations instead of at
once becoming, as it did, the most prominent factor
in the new method of production. The improved
application of these inventions in the first decades
of the nineteenth century mark the transition from
the domestic to the factory system of manufacture and
inaugurated the era of capitalism. The magnitude
of this revolution is manifested by the fact that
England alone had invented the means and equipped
herself with the machinery whereby she could overstock
the world’s markets. The home market could
not consume a tithe of the home product. To
manufacture this home product she had sacrificed her
agriculture. She must buy her food from abroad,
and to do so she must sell her goods abroad.
But the struggle for commercial supremacy
had not yet really begun. England was without
a rival. Her navies controlled the sea.
Her armies and her insular position gave her peace
at home. The world was hers to exploit.
For nearly fifty years she dominated the European,
American, and Indian trade, while the great wars then
convulsing society were destroying possible competitive
capital and straining consumption to its utmost.
The pioneer of the industrial nations, she thus received
such a start in the new race for wealth that it is
only today the other nations have succeeded in overtaking
her. In 1820 the volume of her trade (imports
and exports) was 68,000,000 pounds. In 1899 it
had increased to 815,000,000 pounds, an
increase of 1200 per cent in the volume of trade.
For nearly one hundred years England
has been producing surplus value. She has been
producing far more than she consumes, and this excess
has swelled the volume of her capital. This
capital has been invested in her enterprises at home
and abroad, and in her shipping. In 1898 the
Stock Exchange estimated British capital invested
abroad at 1,900,000,000 pounds. But hand in
hand with her foreign investments have grown her adverse
balances of trade. For the ten years ending with
1868, her average yearly adverse balance was 52,000,000
pounds; ending with 1878, 81,000,000 pounds; ending
with 1888, 101,000,000 pounds; and ending with 1898,
133,000,000 pounds. In the single year of 1897
it reached the portentous sum of 157,000,000 pounds.
But England’s adverse balances
of trade in themselves are nothing at which to be
frightened. Hitherto they have been paid from
out the earnings of her shipping and the interest
on her foreign investments. But what does cause
anxiety, however, is that, relative to the trade development
of other countries, her export trade is falling off,
without a corresponding diminution of her imports,
and that her securities and foreign holdings do not
seem able to stand the added strain. These she
is being forced to sell in order to pull even.
As the London Times gloomily remarks, “We are
entering the twentieth century on the down grade,
after a prolonged period of business activity, high
wages, high profits, and overflowing revenue.”
In other words, the mighty grasp England held over
the resources and capital of the world is being relaxed.
The control of its commerce and banking is slipping
through her fingers. The sale of her foreign
holdings advertises the fact that other nations are
capable of buying them, and, further, that these other
nations are busily producing surplus value.
The movement has become general.
Today, passing from country to country, an ever-increasing
tide of capital is welling up. Production is
doubling and quadrupling upon itself. It used
to be that the impoverished or undeveloped nations
turned to England when it came to borrowing, but now
Germany is competing keenly with her in this matter.
France is not averse to lending great sums to Russia,
and Austria-Hungary has capital and to spare for foreign
holdings.
Nor has the United States failed to
pass from the side of the debtor to that of the creditor
nations. She, too, has become wise in the way
of producing surplus value. She has been successful
in her efforts to secure economic emancipation.
Possessing but 5 per cent of the world’s population
and producing 32 per cent of the world’s food
supply, she has been looked upon as the world’s
farmer; but now, amidst general consternation, she
comes forward as the world’s manufacturer.
In 1888 her manufactured exports amounted to $130,300,087;
in 1896, to $253,681,541; in 1897, to $279,652,721;
in 1898, to $307,924,994; in 1899, to $338,667,794;
and in 1900, to $432,000,000. Regarding her
growing favorable balances of trade, it may be noted
that not only are her imports not increasing, but
they are actually falling off, while her exports in
the last decade have increased 72.4 per cent.
In ten years her imports from Europe have been reduced
from $474,000,000 to $439,000,000; while in the same
time her exports have increased from $682,000,000
to $1,111,000,000. Her balance of trade in her
favor in 1895 was $75,000,000; in 1896, over $100,000,000;
in 1897, nearly $300,000,000; in 1898, $615,000,000;
in 1899, $530,000,000; and in 1900, $648,000,000.
In the matter of iron, the United
States, which in 1840 had not dreamed of entering
the field of international competition, in 1897, as
much to her own surprise as any one else’s,
undersold the English in their own London market.
In 1899 there was but one American locomotive in Great
Britain; but, of the five hundred locomotives sold
abroad by the United States in 1902, England bought
more than any other country. Russia is operating
a thousand of them on her own roads today. In
one instance the American manufacturers contracted
to deliver a locomotive in four and one-half months
for $9250, the English manufacturers requiring twenty-four
months for delivery at $14,000. The Clyde shipbuilders
recently placed orders for 150,000 tons of plates at
a saving of $250,000, and the American steel going
into the making of the new London subway is taken
as a matter of course. American tools stand above
competition the world over. Ready-made boots
and shoes are beginning to flood Europe, the
same with machinery, bicycles, agricultural implements,
and all kinds of manufactured goods. A correspondent
from Hamburg, speaking of the invasion of American
trade, says: “Incidentally, it may be remarked
that the typewriting machine with which this article
is written, as well as the thousands nay,
hundreds of thousands of others that are
in use throughout the world, were made in America;
that it stands on an American table, in an office
furnished with American desks, bookcases, and chairs,
which cannot be made in Europe of equal quality, so
practical and convenient, for a similar price.”
In 1893 and 1894, because of the distrust
of foreign capital, the United States was forced to
buy back American securities held abroad; but in 1897
and 1898 she bought back American securities held abroad,
not because she had to, but because she chose to.
And not only has she bought back her own securities,
but in the last eight years she has become a buyer
of the securities of other countries. In the
money markets of London, Paris, and Berlin she is
a lender of money. Carrying the largest stock
of gold in the world, the world, in moments of danger,
when crises of international finance loom large, looks
to her vast lending ability for safety.
Thus, in a few swift years, has the
United States drawn up to the van where the great
industrial nations are fighting for commercial and
financial empire. The figures of the race, in
which she passed England, are interesting:
As Mr. Henry Demarest Lloyd has noted,
“When the news reached Germany of the new steel
trust in America, the stocks of the iron and steel
mills listed on the Berlin Bourse fell.”
While Europe has been talking and dreaming of the
greatness which was, the United States has been thinking
and planning and doing for the greatness to be.
Her captains of industry and kings of finance have
toiled and sweated at organizing and consolidating
production and transportation. But this has been
merely the developmental stage, the tuning-up of the
orchestra. With the twentieth century rises
the curtain on the play, a play which shall
have much in it of comedy and a vast deal of tragedy,
and which has been well named The Capitalistic Conquest
of Europe by America. Nations do not die easily,
and one of the first moves of Europe will be the erection
of tariff walls. America, however, will fittingly
reply, for already her manufacturers are establishing
works in France and Germany. And when the German
trade journals refused to accept American advertisements,
they found their country flamingly bill-boarded in
buccaneer American fashion.
M. Leroy-Beaulieu, the French economist,
is passionately preaching a commercial combination
of the whole Continent against the United States, a
commercial alliance which, he boldly declares, should
become a political alliance. And in this he
is not alone, finding ready sympathy and ardent support
in Austria, Italy, and Germany. Lord Rosebery
said, in a recent speech before the Wolverhampton
Chamber of Commerce: “The Americans, with
their vast and almost incalculable resources, their
acuteness and enterprise, and their huge population,
which will probably be 100,000,000 in twenty years,
together with the plan they have adopted for putting
accumulated wealth into great cooperative syndicates
or trusts for the purpose of carrying on this great
commercial warfare, are the most formidable . . .
rivals to be feared.”
The London Times says: “It
is useless to disguise the fact that Great Britain
is being outdistanced. The competition does not
come from the glut caused by miscalculation as to
the home demand. Our own steel-makers know better
and are alarmed. The threatened competition in
markets hitherto our own comes from efficiency in production
such as never before has been seen.” Even
the British naval supremacy is in danger, continues
the same paper, “for, if we lose our engineering
supremacy, our naval supremacy will follow, unless
held on sufferance by our successful rivals.”
And the Edinburgh Evening News says,
with editorial gloom: “The iron and steel
trades have gone from us. When the fictitious
prosperity caused by the expenditure of our own Government
and that of European nations on armaments ceases,
half of the men employed in these industries will be
turned into the streets. The outlook is appalling.
What suffering will have to be endured before the
workers realize that there is nothing left for them
but emigration!”
That there must be a limit to the
accumulation of capital is obvious. The downward
course of the rate of interest, notwithstanding that
many new employments have been made possible for capital,
indicates how large is the increase of surplus value.
This decline of the interest rate is in accord with
Bohm-Bawerk’s law of “diminishing returns.”
That is, when capital, like anything else, has become
over-plentiful, less lucrative use can only be found
for the excess. This excess, not being able to
earn so much as when capital was less plentiful, competes
for safe investments and forces down the interest
rate on all capital. Mr. Charles A. Conant has
well described the keenness of the scramble for safe
investments, even at the prevailing low rates of interest.
At the close of the war with Turkey, the Greek loan,
guaranteed by Great Britain, France, and Russia, was
floated with striking ease. Regardless of the
small return, the amount offered at Paris, (41,000,000
francs), was subscribed for twenty-three times over.
Great Britain, France, Germany, Holland, and the
Scandinavian States, of recent years, have all engaged
in converting their securities from 5 per cents to
4 per cents, from 4.5 per cents to 3.5 per cents,
and the 3.5 per cents into 3 per cents.
Great Britain, France, Germany, and
Austria-Hungary, according to the calculation taken
in 1895 by the International Statistical Institute,
hold forty-six billions of capital invested in negotiable
securities alone. Yet Paris subscribed for her
portion of the Greek loan twenty-three times over!
In short, money is cheap. Andrew Carnegie and
his brother bourgeois kings give away millions annually,
but still the tide wells up. These vast accumulations
have made possible “wild-catting,” fraudulent
combinations, fake enterprises, Hooleyism; but such
stealings, great though they be, have little or no
effect in reducing the volume. The time is past
when startling inventions, or revolutions in the method
of production, can break up the growing congestion;
yet this saved capital demands an outlet, somewhere,
somehow.
When a great nation has equipped itself
to produce far more than it can, under the present
division of the product, consume, it seeks other markets
for its surplus products. When a second nation
finds itself similarly circumstanced, competition
for these other markets naturally follows. With
the advent of a third, a fourth, a fifth, and of divers
other nations, the question of the disposal of surplus
products grows serious. And with each of these
nations possessing, over and beyond its active capital,
great and growing masses of idle capital, and when
the very foreign markets for which they are competing
are beginning to produce similar wares for themselves,
the question passes the serious stage and becomes
critical.
Never has the struggle for foreign
markets been sharper than at the present. They
are the one great outlet for congested accumulations.
Predatory capital wanders the world over, seeking where
it may establish itself. This urgent need for
foreign markets is forcing upon the world-stage an
era of great colonial empire. But this does not
stand, as in the past, for the subjugation of peoples
and countries for the sake of gaining their products,
but for the privilege of selling them products.
The theory once was, that the colony owed its existence
and prosperity to the mother country; but today it
is the mother country that owes its existence and
prosperity to the colony. And in the future,
when that supporting colony becomes wise in the way
of producing surplus value and sends its goods back
to sell to the mother country, what then? Then
the world will have been exploited, and capitalistic
production will have attained its maximum development.
Foreign markets and undeveloped countries
largely retard that moment. The favored portions
of the earth’s surface are already occupied,
though the resources of many are yet virgin.
That they have not long since been wrested from the
hands of the barbarous and decadent peoples who possess
them is due, not to the military prowess of such peoples,
but to the jealous vigilance of the industrial nations.
The powers hold one another back. The Turk
lives because the way is not yet clear to an amicable
division of him among the powers. And the United
States, supreme though she is, opposes the partition
of China, and intervenes her huge bulk between the
hungry nations and the mongrel Spanish republics.
Capital stands in its own way, welling up and welling
up against the inevitable moment when it shall burst
all bonds and sweep resistlessly across such vast
stretches as China and South America. And then
there will be no more worlds to exploit, and capitalism
will either fall back, crushed under its own weight,
or a change of direction will take place which will
mark a new era in history.
The Far East affords an illuminating
spectacle. While the Western nations are crowding
hungrily in, while the Partition of China is commingled
with the clamor for the Spheres of Influence and the
Open Door, other forces are none the less potently
at work. Not only are the young Western peoples
pressing the older ones to the wall, but the East
itself is beginning to awake. American trade
is advancing, and British trade is losing ground,
while Japan, China, and India are taking a hand in
the game themselves.
In 1893, 100,000 pieces of American
drills were imported into China; in 1897, 349,000.
In 1893, 252,000 pieces of American sheetings were
imported against 71,000 British; but in 1897, 566,000
pieces of American sheetings were imported against
only 10,000 British. The cotton goods and yarn
trade (which forms 40 per cent of the whole trade with
China) shows a remarkable advance on the part of the
United States. During the last ten years America
has increased her importation of plain goods by 121
per cent in quantity and 59.5 per cent in value, while
that of England and India combined has decreased 13.75
per cent in quantity and 8 per cent in value.
Lord Charles Beresford, from whose “Break-up
of China” these figures are taken, states that
English yarn has receded and Indian yarn advanced
to the front. In 1897, 140,000 piculs of Indian
yarn were imported, 18,000 of Japanese, 4500 of Shanghai-manufactured,
and 700 of English.
Japan, who but yesterday emerged from
the mediaeval rule of the Shogunate and seized in
one fell swoop the scientific knowledge and culture
of the Occident, is already today showing what wisdom
she has acquired in the production of surplus value,
and is preparing herself that she may tomorrow play
the part to Asia that England did to Europe one hundred
years ago. That the difference in the world’s
affairs wrought by those one hundred years will prevent
her succeeding is manifest; but it is equally manifest
that they cannot prevent her playing a leading part
in the industrial drama which has commenced on the
Eastern stage. Her imports into the port of
Newchang in 1891 amounted to but 22,000 taels; but
in 1897 they had increased to 280,000 taels.
In manufactured goods, from matches, watches, and
clocks to the rolling stock of railways, she has already
given stiff shocks to her competitors in the Asiatic
markets; and this while she is virtually yet in the
equipment stage of production. Erelong she, too,
will be furnishing her share to the growing mass of
the world’s capital.
As regards Great Britain, the giant
trader who has so long overshadowed Asiatic commerce,
Lord Charles Beresford says: “But competition
is telling adversely; the energy of the British merchant
is being equalled by other nationals. . . The
competition of the Chinese and the introduction of
steam into the country are also combining to produce
changed conditions in China.” But far more
ominous is the plaintive note he sounds when he says:
“New industries must be opened up, and I would
especially direct the attention of the Chambers of
Commerce (British) to . . . the fact that the more
the native competes with the British manufacturer
in certain classes of trade, the more machinery he
will need, and the orders for such machinery will
come to this country if our machinery manufacturers
are enterprising enough.”
The Orient is beginning to show what
an important factor it will become, under Western
supervision, in the creation of surplus value.
Even before the barriers which restrain Western capital
are removed, the East will be in a fair way toward
being exploited. An analysis of Lord Beresford’s
message to the Chambers of Commerce discloses, first,
that the East is beginning to manufacture for itself;
and, second, that there is a promise of keen competition
in the West for the privilege of selling the required
machinery. The inexorable query arises:
What is the West to do when it has furnished this
machinery? And when not only the East, but
all the now undeveloped countries, confront, with
surplus products in their hands, the old industrial
nations, capitalistic production will have attained
its maximum development.
But before that time must intervene
a period which bids one pause for breath. A
new romance, like unto none in all the past, the economic
romance, will be born. For the dazzling prize
of world-empire will the nations of the earth go up
in harness. Powers will rise and fall, and mighty
coalitions shape and dissolve in the swift whirl
of events. Vassal nations and subject territories
will be bandied back and forth like so many articles
of trade. And with the inevitable displacement
of economic centres, it is fair to presume that populations
will shift to and fro, as they once did from the South
to the North of England on the rise of the factory
towns, or from the Old World to the New. Colossal
enterprises will be projected and carried through,
and combinations of capital and federations of labor
be effected on a cyclopean scale. Concentration
and organization will be perfected in ways hitherto
undreamed. The nation which would keep its head
above the tide must accurately adjust supply to demand,
and eliminate waste to the last least particle.
Standards of living will most likely descend for millions
of people. With the increase of capital, the
competition for safe investments, and the consequent
fall of the interest rate, the principal which today
earns a comfortable income would not then support a
bare existence. Saving toward old age would
cease among the working classes. And as the merchant
cities of Italy crashed when trade slipped from their
hands on the discovery of the new route to the Indies
by way of the Cape of Good Hope, so will there come
times of trembling for such nations as have failed
to grasp the prize of world-empire. In that given
direction they will have attained their maximum development,
before the whole world, in the same direction, has
attained its. There will no longer be room for
them. But if they can survive the shock of being
flung out of the world’s industrial orbit, a
change in direction may then be easily effected.
That the decadent and barbarous peoples will be crushed
is a fair presumption; likewise that the stronger
breeds will survive, entering upon the transition
stage to which all the world must ultimately come.
This change of direction must be either
toward industrial oligarchies or socialism.
Either the functions of private corporations will
increase till they absorb the central government,
or the functions of government will increase till
it absorbs the corporations. Much may be said
on the chance of the oligarchy. Should an old
manufacturing nation lose its foreign trade, it is
safe to predict that a strong effort would be made
to build a socialistic government, but it does not
follow that this effort would be successful.
With the moneyed class controlling the State and
its revenues and all the means of subsistence, and
guarding its own interests with jealous care, it is
not at all impossible that a strong curb could be
put upon the masses till the crisis were past.
It has been done before. There is no reason
why it should not be done again. At the close
of the last century, such a movement was crushed by
its own folly and immaturity. In 1871 the soldiers
of the economic rulers stamped out, root and branch,
a whole generation of militant socialists.
Once the crisis were past, the ruling
class, still holding the curb in order to make itself
more secure, would proceed to readjust things and to
balance consumption with production. Having a
monopoly of the safe investments, the great masses
of unremunerative capital would be directed, not to
the production of more surplus value, but to the making
of permanent improvements, which would give employment
to the people, and make them content with the new
order of things. Highways, parks, public buildings,
monuments, could be builded; nor would it be out of
place to give better factories and homes to the workers.
Such in itself would be socialistic, save that it
would be done by the oligarchs, a class apart.
With the interest rate down to zero, and no field for
the investment of sporadic capital, savings among
the people would utterly cease, and old-age pensions
be granted as a matter of course. It is also
a logical necessity of such a system that, when the
population began to press against the means of subsistence,
(expansion being impossible), the birth rate of the
lower classes would be lessened. Whether by their
own initiative, or by the interference of the rulers,
it would have to be done, and it would be done.
In other words, the oligarchy would mean the capitalization
of labor and the enslavement of the whole population.
But it would be a fairer, juster form of slavery
than any the world has yet seen. The per capita
wage and consumption would be increased, and, with
a stringent control of the birth rate, there is no
reason why such a country should not be so ruled through
many generations.
On the other hand, as the capitalistic
exploitation of the planet approaches its maximum,
and countries are crowded out of the field of foreign
exchanges, there is a large likelihood that their change
in direction will be toward socialism. Were
the theory of collective ownership and operation then
to arise for the first time, such a movement would
stand small chance of success. But such is not
the case. The doctrine of socialism has flourished
and grown throughout the nineteenth century; its tenets
have been preached wherever the interests of labor
and capital have clashed; and it has received exemplification
time and again by the State’s assumption of
functions which had always belonged solely to the
individual.
When capitalistic production has attained
its maximum development, it must confront a dividing
of the ways; and the strength of capital on the one
hand, and the education and wisdom of the workers on
the other, will determine which path society is to
travel. It is possible, considering the inertia
of the masses, that the whole world might in time come
to be dominated by a group of industrial oligarchies,
or by one great oligarchy, but it is not probable.
That sporadic oligarchies may flourish for definite
periods of time is highly possible; that they may
continue to do so is as highly improbable. The
procession of the ages has marked not only the rise
of man, but the rise of the common man. From
the chattel slave, or the serf chained to the soil,
to the highest seats in modern society, he has risen,
rung by rung, amid the crumbling of the divine right
of kings and the crash of falling sceptres. That
he has done this, only in the end to pass into the
perpetual slavery of the industrial oligarch, is something
at which his whole past cries in protest. The
common man is worthy of a better future, or else he
is not worthy of his past.
NOTE. The above article
was written as long ago as 1898. The only alteration
has been the bringing up to 1900 of a few of its statistics.
As a commercial venture of an author, it has an interesting
history. It was promptly accepted by one of
the leading magazines and paid for. The editor
confessed that it was “one of those articles
one could not possibly let go of after it was once
in his possession.” Publication was voluntarily
promised to be immediate. Then the editor became
afraid of its too radical nature, forfeited the sum
paid for it, and did not publish it. Nor, offered
far and wide, could any other editor of bourgeois
periodicals be found who was rash enough to publish
it. Thus, for the first time, after seven years,
it appears in print.