MASTERSHIP.
136. As in all previous discussions
of our subject, we must study the relation of the
commanding rich to the obeying poor in its simplest
elements, in order to reach its first principles.
The simplest state of it, then, is
this: a wise and provident person works much,
consumes little, and lays by a store; an improvident
person works little, consumes all his produce, and
lays by no store. Accident interrupts the daily
work, or renders it less productive; the idle person
must then starve, or be supported by the provident
one, who, having him thus at his mercy, may either
refuse to maintain him altogether, or, which will
evidently be more to his own interest, say to him,
“I will maintain you, indeed, but you shall now
work hard, instead of indolently, and instead of being
allowed to lay by what you save, as you might have
done, had you remained independent, I will take
all the surplus. You would not lay it up for
yourself; it is wholly your own fault that has thrown
you into my power, and I will force you to work, or
starve; yet you shall have no profit of your work,
only your daily bread for it; [and competition shall
determine how much of that].” This
mode of treatment has now become so universal that
it is supposed to be the only natural nay,
the only possible one; and the market wages are calmly
defined by economists as “the sum which will
maintain the labourer.”
137. The power of the provident
person to do this is only checked by the correlative
power of some neighbour of similarly frugal habits,
who says to the labourer “I will
give you a little more than this other provident person:
come and work for me.”
The power of the provident over the
improvident depends thus, primarily, on their relative
numbers; secondarily, on the modes of agreement of
the adverse parties with each other. The accidental
level of wages is a variable function of the number
of provident and idle persons in the world, of the
enmity between them as classes, and of the agreement
between those of the same class. It depends, from
beginning to end, on moral conditions.
138. Supposing the rich to be
entirely selfish, it is always for their interest
that the poor should be as numerous as they can employ,
and restrain. For, granting that the entire
population is no larger than the ground can easily
maintain that the classes are stringently
divided and that there is sense or strength
of hand enough with the rich to secure obedience;
then, if nine-tenths of a nation are poor, the remaining
tenth have the service of nine persons each; but,
if eight-tenths are poor, only of four each; if seven-tenths
are poor, of two and a third each; if six-tenths are
poor, of one and a half each; and if five-tenths are
poor, of only one each. But, practically, if the
rich strive always to obtain more power over the poor,
instead of to raise them and if, on the
other hand, the poor become continually more vicious
and numerous, through neglect and oppression, though
the range of the power of the rich increases,
its tenure becomes less secure; until, at last
the measure of iniquity being full, revolution, civil
war, or the subjection of the state to a healthier
or stronger one, closes the moral corruption, and
industrial disease.
139. It is rarely, however, that
things come to this extremity. Kind persons among
the rich, and wise among the poor, modify the connexion
of the classes: the efforts made to raise and
relieve on the one side, and the success of honest
toil on the other, bind and blend the orders of society
into the confused tissue of half-felt obligation,
sullenly-rendered obedience, and variously-directed,
or mis-directed toil, which form the warp of
daily life. But this great law rules all the
wild design: that success (while society is guided
by laws of competition) signifies always so much
victory over your neighbour as to obtain the direction
of his work, and to take the profits of it. This
is the real source of all great riches. No man
can become largely rich by his personal toil.
The work of his own hands, wisely directed, will indeed
always maintain himself and his family, and make fitting
provision for his age. But it is only by the discovery
of some method of taxing the labour of others that
he can become opulent. Every increase of his capital
enables him to extend this taxation more widely; that
is, to invest larger funds in the maintenance of labourers, to
direct, accordingly, vaster and yet vaster masses of
labour, and to appropriate its profits.
140. There is much confusion
of idea on the subject of this appropriation.
It is, of course, the interest of the employer to
disguise it from the persons employed; and, for his
own comfort and complacency, he often desires no less
to disguise it from himself. And it is matter
of much doubt with me, how far the foul and foolish
arguments used habitually on this subject are indeed
the honest expression of foul and foolish convictions; or
rather (as I am sometimes forced to conclude from
the irritation with which they are advanced) are resolutely
dishonest, wilful, and malicious sophisms, arranged
so as to mask, to the last moment, the real laws of
economy, and future duties of men. By taking
a simple example, and working it thoroughly out, the
subject may be rescued from all but such determined
misrepresentation.
141. Let us imagine a society
of peasants, living on a rivershore, exposed to destructive
inundation at somewhat extended intervals; and that
each peasant possesses of this good, but imperilled,
ground, more than he needs to cultivate for immediate
subsistence. We will assume farther (and with
too great probability of justice), that the greater
part of them indolently keep in tillage just as much
land as supplies them with daily food; that
they leave their children idle, and take no precautions
against the rise of the stream. But one of them,
(we will say but one, for the sake of greater clearness)
cultivates carefully all the ground of his
estate; makes his children work hard and healthily;
uses his spare time and theirs in building a rampart
against the river; and, at the end of some years,
has in his storehouses large reserves of food and
clothing, in his stables a well-tended breed
of cattle, and around his fields a wedge of wall against
flood.
The torrent rises at last sweeps
away the harvests, and half the cottages of the careless
peasants, and leaves them destitute. They naturally
come for help to the provident one, whose fields are
unwasted, and whose granaries are full. He has
the right to refuse it to them: no one disputes
this right. But he will probably not refuse
it; it is not his interest to do so, even were he
entirely selfish and cruel. The only question
with him will be on what terms his aid is to be granted.
142. Clearly, not on terms of
mere charity. To maintain his neighbours in idleness
would be not only his ruin, but theirs. He will
require work from them, in exchange for their maintenance;
and, whether in kindness or cruelty, all the work
they can give. Not now the three or four hours
they were wont to spend on their own land, but the
eight or ten hours they ought to have spent. But
how will he apply this labour? The men are now
his slaves; nothing less, and nothing more.
On pain of starvation, he can force them to work in
the manner, and to the end, he chooses. And it
is by his wisdom in this choice that the worthiness
of his mastership is proved, or its unworthiness.
Evidently, he must first set them to bank out the
water in some temporary way, and to get their ground
cleansed and resown; else, in any case, their continued
maintenance will be impossible. That done, and
while he has still to feed them, suppose he makes
them raise a secure rampart for their own ground against
all future flood, and rebuild their houses in safer
places, with the best material they can find; being
allowed time out of their working hours to fetch such
material from a distance. And for the food and
clothing advanced, he takes security in land that as
much shall be returned at a convenient period.
143. We may conceive this security
to be redeemed, and the debt paid at the end of a
few years. The prudent peasant has sustained no
loss; but is no richer than he was, and has had
all his trouble for nothing. But he has enriched
his neighbours materially; bettered their houses,
secured their land, and rendered them, in worldly matters,
equal to himself. In all rational and final sense,
he has been throughout their true Lord and King.
144. We will next trace his probable
line of conduct, presuming his object to be exclusively
the increase of his own fortune. After roughly
recovering and cleansing the ground, he allows the
ruined peasantry only to build huts upon it, such
as he thinks protective enough from the weather to
keep them in working health. The rest of their
time he occupies, first in pulling down, and rebuilding
on a magnificent scale, his own house, and in adding
large dependencies to it. This done, in exchange
for his continued supply of corn, he buys as much of
his neighbours’ land as he thinks he can superintend
the management of; and makes the former owners securely
embank and protect the ceded portion. By this
arrangement, he leaves to a certain number of the peasantry
only as much ground as will just maintain them in
their existing numbers; as the population increases,
he takes the extra hands, who cannot be maintained
on the narrowed estates, for his own servants; employs
some to cultivate the ground he has bought, giving
them of its produce merely enough for subsistence;
with the surplus, which, under his energetic and careful
superintendence, will be large, he maintains a train
of servants for state, and a body of workmen, whom
he educates in ornamental arts. He now can splendidly
decorate his house, lay out its grounds magnificently,
and richly supply his table, and that of his household
and retinue. And thus, without any abuse of right,
we should find established all the phenomena of poverty
and riches, which (it is supposed necessarily) accompany
modern civilization. In one part of the district,
we should have unhealthy land, miserable dwellings,
and half-starved poor; in another, a well-ordered
estate, well-fed servants, and refined conditions
of highly educated and luxurious life.
145. I have put the two cases
in simplicity, and to some extremity. But though
in more complex and qualified operation, all the relations
of society are but the expansion of these two typical
sequences of conduct and result. I do not say,
observe, that the first procedure is entirely recommendable;
or even entirely right; still less, that the second
is wholly wrong. Servants, and artists, and splendour
of habitation and retinue, have all their use, propriety,
and office. But I am determined that the reader
shall understand clearly what they cost; and see that
the condition of having them is the subjection to us
of a certain number of imprudent or unfortunate persons
(or, it may be, more fortunate than their masters),
over whose destinies we exercise a boundless control.
“Riches” mean eternally and essentially
this; and God send at last a time when those words
of our best-reputed economist shall be true, and we
shall indeed “all know what it is to be
rich;" that it is to be slave-master over farthest
earth, and over all ways and thoughts of men.
Every operative you employ is your true servant:
distant or near, subject to your immediate orders,
or ministering to your widely-communicated caprice, for
the pay he stipulates, or the price he tempts, all
are alike under this great dominion of the gold.
The milliner who makes the dress is as much a servant
(more so, in that she uses more intelligence in the
service) as the maid who puts it on; the carpenter
who smooths the door, as the footman who opens it;
the tradesmen who supply the table, as the labourers
and sailors who supply the tradesmen. Why speak
of these lower services? Painters and singers
(whether of note or rhyme,) jesters and storytellers,
moralists, historians, priests, so far
as these, in any degree, paint, or sing, or tell their
tale, or charm their charm, or “perform”
their rite, for pay, in so far,
they are all slaves; abject utterly, if the service
be for pay only; abject less and less in proportion
to the degrees of love and of wisdom which enter into
their duty, or can enter into it, according
as their function is to do the bidding and the work
of a manly people; or to amuse, tempt,
and deceive, a childish one.
146. There is always, in such
amusement and temptation, to a certain extent, a government
of the rich by the poor, as of the poor by the rich;
but the latter is the prevailing and necessary one,
and it consists, when it is honourable, in the collection
of the profits of labour from those who would have
misused them, and the administration of those profits
for the service either of the same persons in future,
or of others; and when it is dishonourable, as is
more frequently the case in modern times, it consists
in the collection of the profits of labour from those
who would have rightly used them, and their appropriation
to the service of the collector himself.
147. The examination of these
various modes of collection and use of riches will
form the third branch of our future inquiries; but
the key to the whole subject lies in the clear understanding
of the difference between selfish and unselfish expenditure.
It is not easy, by any course of reasoning, to enforce
this on the generally unwilling hearer; yet the definition
of unselfish expenditure is brief and simple.
It is expenditure which, if you are a capitalist,
does not pay you, but pays somebody else; and
if you are a consumer, does not please you,
but pleases somebody else. Take one special instance,
in further illustration of the general type given
above. I did not invent that type, but spoke
of a real river, and of real peasantry, the languid
and sickly race which inhabits, or haunts for
they are often more like spectres than living men the
thorny desolation of the banks of the Arve in Savoy.
Some years ago, a society, formed at Geneva, offered
to embank the river for the ground which would have
been recovered by the operation; but the offer was
refused by the (then Sardinian) government. The
capitalists saw that this expenditure would have “paid”
if the ground saved from the river was to be theirs.
But if, when the offer that had this aspect of profit
was refused, they had nevertheless persisted in the
plan, and merely taking security for the return of
their outlay, lent the funds for the work, and thus
saved a whole race of human souls from perishing in
a pestiferous fen (as, I presume, some among them
would, at personal risk, have dragged any one drowning
creature out of the current of the stream, and not
expected payment therefor), such expenditure would
have precisely corresponded to the use of his power
made, in the first instance, by our supposed richer
peasant it would have been the king’s,
of grace, instead of the usurer’s, for gain.
148. “Impossible, absurd,
Utopian!” exclaim nine-tenths of the few readers
whom these words may find.
No, good reader, this is not
Utopian: but I will tell you what would have
seemed, if we had not seen it, Utopian on the side
of evil instead of good; that ever men should have
come to value their money so much more than their
lives, that if you call upon them to become soldiers,
and take chance of a bullet through their heart, and
of wife and children being left desolate, for their
pride’s sake, they will do it gaily, without
thinking twice; but if you ask them, for their country’s
sake, to spend a hundred pounds without security of
getting back a hundred-and-five, they will laugh
in your face.
149. Not but that also this game
of life-giving and taking is, in the end, somewhat
more costly than other forms of play might be.
Rifle practice is, indeed, a not unhealthy pastime,
and a feather on the top of the head is a pleasing
appendage; but while learning the stops and fingering
of the sweet instrument, does no one ever calculate
the cost of an overture? What melody does Tityrus
meditate on his tenderly spiral pipe? The leaden
seed of it, broadcast, true conical “Dents de
Lion” seed needing less allowance
for the wind than is usual with that kind of herb what
crop are you likely to have of it? Suppose, instead
of this volunteer marching and countermarching, you
were to do a little volunteer ploughing and counter-ploughing?
It is more difficult to do it straight: the dust
of the earth, so disturbed, is more grateful than for
merely rhythmic footsteps. Golden cups, also,
given for good ploughing, would be more suitable in
colour: (ruby glass, for the wine which “giveth
his colour” on the ground, might be fitter for
the rifle prize in ladies’ hands). Or,
conceive a little volunteer exercise with the spade,
other than such as is needed for moat and breastwork,
or even for the burial of the fruit of the leaden
avena-seed, subject to the shrill Lemures’
criticism
Wer hat das
Haus so schlecht gebauet?
If you were to embank Lincolnshire
more stoutly against the sea? or strip the peat of
Solway, or plant Plinlimmon moors with larch then,
in due season, some amateur reaping and threshing?
“Nay, we reap
and thresh by steam, in these advanced days.”
I know it, my wise and economical
friends. The stout arms God gave you to win your
bread by, you would fain shoot your neighbours, and
God’s sweet singers with; then you invoke
the fiends to your farm-service; and
When young and old come forth
to play
On a sulphurous holiday,
Tell how the darkling goblin
sweat
(His feast of cinders duly
set),
And, belching night, where
breathed the morn,
His shadowy flail hath threshed
the corn
That ten day-labourers could
not end.
150. Going back to the matter
in hand, we will press the example closer. On
a green knoll above that plain of the Arve, between
Cluse and Bonneville, there was, in the year
1860, a cottage, inhabited by a well-doing family man
and wife, three children, and the grandmother.
I call it a cottage, but in truth, it was a large
chimney on the ground, wide at the bottom, so that
the family might live round the fire; lighted by one
small broken window, and entered by an unclosing door.
The family, I say, was “well-doing;” at
least it was hopeful and cheerful; the wife healthy,
the children, for Savoyards, pretty and active, but
the husband threatened with decline, from exposure
under the cliffs of the Mont Vergi by day, and to
draughts between every plank of his chimney in the
frosty nights.
“Why could he not plaster the
chinks?” asks the practical reader. For
the same reason that your child cannot wash its face
and hands till you have washed them many a day for
it, and will not wash them when it can, till you force
it.
151. I passed this cottage often
in my walks, had its window and door mended; sometimes
mended also a little the meal of sour bread and broth,
and generally got kind greeting and smile from the
face of young or old; which greeting this year, narrowed
itself into the half-recognizing stare of the elder
child, and the old woman’s tears; for the father
and mother were both dead, one of sickness,
the other of sorrow. It happened that I passed
not alone, but with a companion, a practised English
joiner, who, while these people were dying of cold,
had been employed from six in the morning to six in
the evening, for two months, in fitting, without nails,
the panels of a single door in a large house in London.
Three days of his work taken, at the right time from
fastening the oak panels with useless precision, and
applied to fasten the larch timbers with decent strength,
would have saved these Savoyards’ lives. He
would have been maintained equally; (I suppose him
equally paid for his work by the owner of the greater
house, only the work not consumed selfishly on his
own walls;) and the two peasants, and eventually,
probably their children, saved.
152. There are, therefore, let
me finally enforce, and leave with the reader, this
broad conclusion, three things to be considered
in employing any poor person. It is not enough
to give him employment. You must employ him first
to produce useful things; secondly, of the several
(suppose equally useful) things he can equally well
produce, you must set him to make that which will
cause him to lead the healthiest life; lastly, of
the things produced, it remains a question of wisdom
and conscience how much you are to take yourself,
and how much to leave to others. A large quantity,
remember, unless you destroy it, must always
be so left at one time or another; the only questions
you have to decide are, not what you will give,
but when, and how, and to whom,
you will give. The natural law of human life
is, of course, that in youth a man shall labour and
lay by store for his old age, and when age comes,
shall use what he has laid by, gradually slackening
his toil, and allowing himself more frank use of his
store; taking care always to leave himself as much
as will surely suffice for him beyond any possible
length of life. What he has gained, or by tranquil
and unanxious toil continues to gain, more than is
enough for his own need, he ought so to administer,
while he yet lives, as to see the good of it again
beginning, in other hands; for thus he has himself
the greatest sum of pleasure from it, and faithfully
uses his sagacity in its control. Whereas most
men, it appears, dislike the sight of their fortunes
going out into service again, and say to themselves, “I
can indeed nowise prevent this money from falling
at last into the hands of others, nor hinder the good
of it from becoming theirs, not mine; but at least
let a merciful death save me from being a witness
of their satisfaction; and may God so far be gracious
to me as to let no good come of any of this money
of mine before my eyes.”
153. Supposing this feeling unconquerable,
the safest way of rationally indulging it would be
for the capitalist at once to spend all his fortune
on himself, which might actually, in many cases, be
quite the rightest as well as the pleasantest thing
to do, if he had just tastes and worthy passions.
But, whether for himself only, or through the hands,
and for the sake, of others also, the law of wise life
is, that the maker of the money shall also be the
spender of it, and spend it, approximately, all, before
he dies; so that his true ambition as an economist
should be, to die, not as rich, but as poor, as possible,
calculating the ebb tide of possession in true and
calm proportion to the ebb tide of life. Which
law, checking the wing of accumulative desire in the
mid-volley, and leading to peace of possession
and fulness of fruition in old age, is also wholesome,
in that by the freedom of gift, together with present
help and counsel, it at once endears and dignifies
age in the sight of youth, which then no longer strips
the bodies of the dead, but receives the grace of the
living. Its chief use would (or will be, for
men are indeed capable of attaining to this much use
of their reason), that some temperance and measure
will be put to the acquisitiveness of commerce.
For as things stand, a man holds it his duty to be
temperate in his food, and of his body, but for no
duty to be temperate in his riches, and of his mind.
He sees that he ought not to waste his youth and his
flesh for luxury; but he will waste his age, and his
soul, for money, and think he does no wrong, nor know
the delirium tremens of the intellect for disease.
But the law of life is, that a man should fix the
sum he desires to make annually, as the food he desires
to eat daily; and stay when he has reached the limit,
refusing increase of business, and leaving it to others,
so obtaining due freedom of time for better thoughts.
How the gluttony of business is punished, a bill of
health for the principals of the richest city houses,
issued annually, would show in a sufficiently impressive
manner.
154. I know, of course, that
these statements will be received by the modern merchant
as an active border rider of the sixteenth century
would have heard of its being proper for men of the
Marches to get their living by the spade, instead
of the spur. But my business is only to state
veracities and necessities; I neither look for the
acceptance of the one, nor hope for the nearness of
the other. Near or distant, the day will
assuredly come when the merchants of a state shall
be its true ministers of exchange, its porters, in
the double sense of carriers and gate-keepers, bringing
all lands into frank and faithful communication, and
knowing for their master of guild, Hermes the herald,
instead of Mercury the gain-guarder.
155. And now, finally, for immediate
rule to all who will accept it.
The distress of any population means
that they need food, house-room, clothes, and fuel.
You can never, therefore, be wrong in employing any
labourer to produce food, house-room, clothes, or fuel;
but you are always wrong if you employ him
to produce nothing, (for then some other labourer
must be worked double time to feed him); and you are
generally wrong, at present, if you employ him (unless
he can do nothing else) to produce works of art or
luxuries; because modern art is mostly on a false
basis, and modern luxury is criminally great.
156. The way to produce more
food is mainly to bring in fresh ground, and increase
facilities of carriage; to break rock, exchange
earth, drain the moist, and water the dry, to mend
roads, and build harbours of refuge. Taxation
thus spent will annihilate taxation, but spent in war,
it annihilates revenue.
157. The way to produce house-room
is to apply your force first to the humblest dwellings.
When your brick-layers are out of employ, do not build
splendid new streets, but better the old ones; send
your paviours and slaters to the poorest villages,
and see that your poor are healthily lodged, before
you try your hand on stately architecture. You
will find its stateliness rise better under the trowel
afterwards; and we do do not yet build so well that
we need hasten to display our skill to future ages.
Had the labour which has decorated the Houses of Parliament
filled, instead, rents in walls and roofs throughout
the county of Middlesex; and our deputies met to talk
within massive walls that would have needed no stucco
for five hundred years, the decoration
might have been afterwards, and the talk now.
And touching even our highly conscientious church
building, it may be well to remember that in the best
days of church plans, their masons called themselves
“logeurs du bon Dieu;” and that since,
according to the most trusted reports, God spends
a good deal of His time in cottages as well as in churches,
He might perhaps like to be a little better lodged
there also.
158. The way to get more clothes
is not, necessarily, to get more cotton.
There were words written twenty years ago which
would have saved many of us some shivering, had they
been minded in time. Shall we read them again?
“The Continental people, it
would seem, are importing our machinery, beginning
to spin cotton, and manufacture for themselves; to
cut us out of this market, and then out of that!
Sad news, indeed; but irremediable. By no means
the saddest news the saddest news, is that
we should find our national existence, as I sometimes
hear it said, depend on selling manufactured cotton
at a farthing an ell cheaper than any other people.
A most narrow stand for a great nation to base itself
on! A stand which, with all the Corn-law abrogations
conceivable, I do not think will be capable of enduring.
“My friends, suppose we quitted
that stand; suppose we came honestly down from it
and said ’This is our minimum of cotton
prices; we care not, for the present, to make cotton
any cheaper. Do you, if it seem so blessed to
you, make cotton cheaper. Fill your lungs with
cotton fur, your heart with copperas fumes, with rage
and mutiny; become ye the general gnomes of Europe,
slaves of the lamp!’ I admire a nation which
fancies it will die if it do not undersell all other
nations to the end of the world. Brothers, we
will cease to undersell them; we will be content to
equal-sell them; to be happy selling equally with them!
I do not see the use of underselling them: cotton-cloth
is already twopence a yard, or lower; and yet bare
backs were never more numerous among us. Let
inventive men cease to spend their existence incessantly
contriving how cotton can be made cheaper; and try
to invent a little how cotton at its present cheapness
could be somewhat justlier divided among us.
“Let inventive men consider whether
the secret of this universe does after all consist
in making money. With a hell which means ’failing
to make money,’ I do not think there is any
heaven possible that would suit one well. In
brief, all this Mammon gospel of supply-and-demand,
competition laissez faire, and devil take the
hindmost (foremost, is it not, rather, Mr. Carlyle?),
’begins to be one of the shabbiest gospels ever
preached.’”
159. The way to produce more
fuel is first to make your coal mines safer, by
sinking more shafts; then set all your convicts to
work in them, and if, as is to be hoped, you succeed
in diminishing the supply of that sort of labourer,
consider what means there may be, first, of growing
forest where its growth will improve climate; secondly,
of splintering the forests which now make continents
of fruitful land pathless and poisonous, into fagots
for fire; so gaining at once dominion icewards
and sunwards. Your steam power has been given
(you will find eventually) for work such as that:
and not for excursion trains, to give the labourer
a moment’s breath, at the peril of his breath
for ever, from amidst the cities which it has crushed
into masses of corruption. When you know how
to build cities, and how to rule them, you will be
able to breathe in their streets, and the “excursion”
will be the afternoon’s walk or game in the
fields round them.
160. “But nothing of this work will pay?”
No; no more than it pays to dust your
rooms, or wash your doorsteps. It will pay; not
at first in currency, but in that which is the end
and the source of currency, in life; (and
in currency richly afterwards). It will pay in
that which is more than life, in light,
whose true price has not yet been reckoned in any
currency, and yet into the image of which, all wealth,
one way or other, must be cast. For your riches
must either be as the lightning, which,
Begot
but in a cloud,
Though shining bright, and
speaking loud,
Whilst it begins, concludes
its violent race;
And, where it gilds, it wounds
the place;
or else, as the lightning of the sacred
sign, which shines from one part of the heaven to
the other. There is no other choice; you must
either take dust for deity, spectre for possession,
fettered dream for life, and for epitaph, this reversed
verse of the great Hebrew hymn of economy (Psalm cxii.): “He
hath gathered together, he hath stripped the poor,
his iniquity remaineth for ever:” or
else, having the sun of justice to shine on you, and
the sincere substance of good in your possession, and
the pure law and liberty of life within you, leave
men to write this better legend over your grave:
“He hath dispersed abroad.
He hath given to the poor. His righteousness
remaineth for ever.”