TO THE SHOP-KEEPERS, TRADESMEN, FARMERS, AND COMMON-PEOPLE
OF IRELAND.
NOTE
About the year 1720 it was generally
acknowledged in Ireland that there was a want there
of the small change, necessary in the transaction of
petty dealings with shopkeepers and tradesmen.
It has been indignantly denied by contemporary writers
that this small change meant copper coins. They
asserted that there was no lack of copper money, but
that there was a great want of small silver.
Be that as it may, the report that small change was
wanting was sufficiently substantiated to the English
government to warrant it to proceed to satisfy the
want. In its dealings with Ireland, however,
English governments appear to have consistently assumed
that attitude which would most likely cause friction
and arouse disturbance. In England coins for currency
proceeded from a mint established under government
supervision. In Scotland such a mint was specially
provided for in the Act of Union. But in Ireland,
the government acted otherwise.
The Irish people had again and again
begged that they should be permitted to establish
a mint in which coins could be issued of the same
standard and intrinsic value as those used in England.
English parliaments, however, invariably disregarded
these petitions. Instead of the mint the King
gave grants or patents by which a private individual
obtained the right to mint coins for the use of the
inhabitants. The right was most often given for
a handsome consideration, and held for a term of years.
In 1660 Charles ii. granted such a patent to Sir
Thomas Armstrong, permitting him to coin farthings
for twenty years. It appears, however, that Armstrong
never actually coined the farthings, although he had
gone to the expense of establishing a costly plant
for the purpose.
Small copper coins becoming scarce,
several individuals, without permission, issued tokens;
but the practice was stopped. In 1680 Sir William
Armstrong, son of Sir Thomas, with Colonel George Legg
(afterwards Lord Dartmouth), obtained a patent for
twenty-one years, granting them the right to issue
copper halfpence. Coins were actually struck
and circulated, but the patent itself was sold to John
Knox in the very year of its issue. Knox, however,
had his patent specially renewed, but his coinage
was interrupted when James ii. issued his debased
money during the Revolution (see Monck Mason, ,
and the notes on this matter to the Drapier’s
Third Letter, in present edition).
Knox sold his patent to Colonel Roger
Moore, who overstocked the country with his coins
to such an extent that the currency became undervalued.
When, in 1705, Moore endeavoured to obtain a renewal
of his patent, his application was refused. By
1722, owing either to Moore’s bad coinage, or
to the importation of debased coins from other countries,
the copper money had degraded considerably. In
a pamphlet issued by George Ewing in Dublin (1724),
it is stated that in that year, W. Trench presented
a memorial to the Lords of the Treasury, complaining
of the condition of the copper coinage, and pointing
out that the evil results had been brought about by
the system of grants to private individuals.
Notwithstanding this memorial, it was attempted to
overcome the difficulty by a continuance of the old
methods. A new patent was issued to an English
iron merchant, William Wood by name, who, according
to Coxe, submitted proposal with many others, for
the amelioration of the grievance. Wood’s
proposals, say this same authority, were accepted “as
beneficial to Ireland.” The letters patent
bear the date July 12th, 1722, and were prepared in
accordance with the King’s instructions to the
Attorney and Solicitor General sent in a letter from
Kensington on June 16th, 1722. The letter commanded
“that a bill should be prepared for his royal
signature, containing and importing an indenture, whereof
one part was to pass the Great Seal of Great Britain.”
This indenture, notes Monck Mason, between His
Majesty of the one part, “and William Wood,
of Wolverhampton, in the County of Stafford, Esq.,”
of the other, signifies that His Majesty
“has received information that,
in his kingdom of Ireland, there was a great want
of small money for making small payments, and that
retailers and others did suffer by reason of such
want.”
By virtue, therefore, of his prerogative
royal, and in consideration of the rents, covenants,
and agreements therein expressed, His Majesty granted
to William Wood, his executors, assigns, etc.,
“full, free, sole, and absolute power, privilege,
licence, and authority,” during fourteen years,
from the annunciation of the Blessed Virgin, 1722,
to coin halfpence and farthings of copper, to be uttered
and disposed of in Ireland, and not elsewhere.
It was provided that the whole quantity coined should
not exceed 360 tons of copper, whereof 100 tons only
were to be coined in the first year, and 20 tons in
each of the last thirteen, said farthings and halfpence
to be of good, pure, and merchantable copper, and
of such size and bigness, that one avoirdupois pound
weight of copper should not be converted into more
farthings and halfpence than would make thirty pence
by tale; all the said farthings and halfpence to be
of equal weight in themselves, or as near thereunto
as might be, allowing a remedy not exceeding two farthings
over or under in each pound. The same “to
pass and to be received as current money, by such
as shall or will, voluntarily and willingly, and not
otherwise, receive the same, within the said kingdom
of Ireland, and not elsewhere.” Wood also
covenanted to pay to the King’s clerk or comptroller
of the coinage, L200 yearly, and L100 per annum into
his Majesty’s treasury.
Most of the accounts of this transaction
and its consequent agitation in Ireland, particularly
those given by Sir W. Scott and Earl Stanhope, are
taken from Coxe’s “Life of Walpole.”
Monck Mason, however, in his various notes appended
to his life of Swift, has once and for all placed
Coxe’s narrative in its true light, and exposed
the specious special pleading on behalf of his hero,
Walpole. But even Coxe cannot hide the fact that
the granting of the patent and the circumstances under
which it was granted, amounted to a disgraceful job,
by which an opportunity was seized to benefit a “noble
person” in England at the expense of Ireland.
The patent was really granted to the King’s mistress,
the Duchess of Kendal, who sold it to William Wood
for the sum of L10,000, and (as it was reported with,
probably, much truth) for a share in the profits of
the coining. The job was alluded to by Swift when
he wrote:
“When late a feminine magician,
Join’d with a brazen politician,
Expos’d, to blind a nation’s eyes,
A parchment of prodigious size.”
Coxe endeavors to exonerate Walpole
from the disgrace attached to this business, by expatiating
on Carteret’s opposition to Walpole, an opposition
which went so far as to attempt to injure the financial
minister’s reputation by fomenting jealousies
and using the Wood patent agitation to arouse against
him the popular indignation; but this does not explain
away the fact itself. He lays some blame for the
agitation on Wood’s indiscretion in flaunting
his rights and publicly boasting of what the great
minister would do for him. At the same time he
takes care to censure the government for its misconduct
in not consulting with the Lord Lieutenant and his
Privy Council before granting the patent. His
censure, however, is founded on the consideration that
this want of attention was injudicious and was the
cause of the spread of exaggerated rumours of the
patent’s evil tendency. He has nothing to
say of the rights and liberties of a people which
had thereby been infringed and ignored.
The English parliament had rarely
shown much consideration for Irish feelings or Irish
rights. Its attitude towards the Irish Houses
of Legislation had been high-handed and even dictatorial;
so that constitutional struggles were not at all infrequent
towards the end of the seventeenth and during the
first quarter of the eighteenth century. The
efforts of Sir Constantine Phipps towards a non-parliamentary
government, and the reversal by the English House
of Lords of the decision given by the Irish House
of Lords in the famous Annesley case, had prepared
the Irish people for a revolt against any further attempts
to dictate to its properly elected representatives
assembled in parliament. Moreover, the wretched
material condition of the people, as it largely had
been brought about by a selfish, persecuting legislation
that practically isolated Ireland commercially in prohibiting
the exportation of its industrial products, was a
danger and a menace to the governing country.
The two nations were facing each other threateningly.
When, therefore, Wood began to import his coin, suspicion
was immediately aroused.
The masses took little notice of it
at first; but the commissioners of revenue in Dublin
took action in a letter they addressed to the Right
Hon. Edward Hopkins, secretary to the Lord Lieutenant.
This letter, dated August 7th, 1722, began by expressing
surprise at the patent granted to Mr. Wood, and asked
the secretary “to lay before the Lord Lieutenant
a memorial, presented by their agent to the Lords of
the Treasury, concerning this patent, and also a report
of some former Commissioners of the revenue on the
like occasion, and to acquaint his Grace, that they
concurred in all the objections in those papers, and
were of opinion, that such a patent would be highly
prejudicial to the trade, and welfare of this kingdom,
and more particularly to his Majesty’s revenue,
which they had formerly found to have suffered very
much, by too great a quantity of such base coin."
No reply was received to this letter.
Fears began to be generally felt,
and the early murmurs of an agitation to be heard
when, on September 19th, 1722, the Commissioners addressed
a second letter, this time to the Lords Commissioners
of His Majesty’s Treasury. The letter assured
their Lordships “that they had been applied
to by many persons of rank and fortune, and by the
merchants and traders in Ireland, to represent the
ill effects of Mr. Wood’s patent, and that they
could from former experience assure their Lordships,
it would be particularly detrimental to his Majesty’s
revenue. They represented that this matter had
made a great noise here, and that there did not appear
the least want of such small species of coin for
change, and hoped that the importance of the occasion
would excuse their making this representation of a
matter that had not been referred to them."
To this letter also no reply was vouchsafed.
In the meantime, Wood kept sending in his coins, landing
them at most of the ports of the kingdom.
“Then everyone that was not
interested in the success of this coinage,”
writes the author of the pamphlet already quoted, “by
having contracted for a great quantity of his halfpence
at a large discount, or biassed by the hopes of immoderate
gain to be made out of the ruins of their country,
expressed their apprehensions of the pernicious consequences
of this copper money; and resolved to make use of
the right they had by law to refuse the same".
The Lord Lieutenant, the Duke of Grafton,
had arrived in August, 1723, and parliament sat early
in September. Its first attention was paid to
the Wood patent. After the early excitement had
subsided, they resolved to appeal to the King.
During the early stages of the discussion, however,
the Commons addressed the Lord Lieutenant, asking that
a copy of the patent and other papers relating to
it, be laid before them. This was on September
13th. On the following day Mr. Hopkins informed
the House that the Lord Lieutenant had no such copy,
nor any papers. The House then unanimously resolved
to inquire into the matter on its own account, and
issued orders for several persons to appear before
it to give evidence, fixing the day for examination
for September 16th. On that day, however, Mr.
Hopkins appeared before the members with a copy of
the patent, and informed them that the Lord Lieutenant
had received it since his last communication with
them. This incident served but to arouse further
ridicule. A broadside, published at the time with
the title “A Creed of an Irish Commoner,”
amusingly reveals the lameness of the excuse for this
non-production of the exemplification. Coxe says
that the cause for the delay was due to the fact that
the copy of the patent had been delivered to the Lord
Lieutenant’s servant, instead of to his private
secretary; but this excuse is probably no more happily
founded than the one offered.
On Friday, September 20th, the House
resolved itself into a committee “to take into
consideration the state of the nation, particularly
in relation to the importing and uttering of copper
halfpence and farthings in this kingdom.”
After three days’ debate, and after examining
competent witnesses under oath, it passed resolutions
to the following effect
(1) That Wood’s patent is highly
prejudicial to his Majesty’s revenue, and is
destructive of trade and commerce, and most dangerous
to the rights and properties of the subject.
(2) That for the purpose of obtaining
the patent Wood had notoriously misrepresented the
state of the nation.
(3) That great quantities of the coin
had been imported of different impressions and of
much less weight than the patent called for.
(4) That the loss to the nation by
the uttering of this coin would amount to 150 per
cent.
(5) That in coining the halfpence
Wood was guilty of a notorious fraud.
(6) “That it is the opinion
of this Committee, that it hath been always highly
prejudicial to this kingdom to grant the power or privilege
of coining money to private persons; and that it will,
at all times, be of dangerous consequence to grant
any such power to any body politic, or corporate,
or any private person or persons whatsoever."
Addresses to his Majesty in conformity
with these resolutions were voted on September 27th.
The House of Lords passed similar
resolutions on September 26th, and voted addresses
embodying them on September 28th.
These Addresses received a better
attention than did the letters from the revenue commissioners.
The Houses were courteously informed that their communications
would receive His Majesty’s careful consideration.
Walpole kept his promise, but not before he had fought
hard to maintain the English prerogative, as he might
have called it. The “secret” history
as narrated in Coxe’s lively manner, throws some
light on the situation. Coxe really finds his
hero’s conduct not marked with “his usual
caution.” The Lord Lieutenant was permitted
to go to Ireland without proper instructions; the
information on which Walpole acted was not reliable;
and he did not sufficiently appreciate the influence
of Chancellor Midleton and his family. “He
bitterly accused Lord Midleton of treachery and low
cunning, of having made, in his speeches, distinction
between the King and his ministers, of caballing with
Carteret, Cadogan, and Roxburgh, and of pursuing that
line of conduct, because he was of opinion the opposite
party would gain the ascendency in the cabinet.
He did not believe the disturbances to be so serious
as they were represented, nor was he satisfied with
the Duke of Grafton’s conduct, as being solely
directed by Conolly, but declared that the part acted
by Conolly, almost excused what the Brodricks had done.”
Carteret complained to the King and proved to him
that Walpole’s policy was a dangerous one.
The King became irritated and Walpole “ashamed.”
He even became “uneasy,” and it is to
be supposed, took a more “cautious” course;
for he managed to conciliate the Brodricks and the
powers in Dublin. But the devil was not ill long.
The cabinet crisis resulted in the triumph of Townshend
and Walpole, and the devil got well again. Carteret
must be removed and the patent promoted. But Midleton
and the Brodricks must be kept friendly. So Carteret
went to Ireland as Lord Lieutenant, Midleton remained
Chancellor, and constituted a lord justice, and St.
John Brodrick was nominated a member of the Privy
Council. Still farther on his “cautious”
way, Ireland must be given some consideration; hence
the Committee of the Privy Council, specially called
to inquire into the grievances complained of by the
Irish Houses of Parliament in their loyal addresses.
The Committee sat for several weeks,
and the report it issued forms the subject of Swift’s
animadversions in the Drapier’s third letter.
But the time spent by the Committee in London was
being utilized in quite a different fashion by Swift
in Ireland. “Cautious” as was Walpole,
he had not reckoned with the champion of his political
opponents of Queen Anne’s days. Swift had
little humour for court intrigues and cabinet cabals.
He came out into the open to fight the good fight of
the people to whom courts and cabinets should be servants
and not self-seeking masters. Whatever doubts
the people of Ireland may have had about the legal
validity of their resentment towards Wood and his coins,
were quickly dissipated when they read “A Letter
to the Shop Keepers, Tradesmen, Farmers, and Common
People of Ireland, concerning the Brass Half-pence
coined by Mr. Wood,” and signed, “M.B.
Drapier.” The letter, as Lord Orrery remarked,
acted like the sound of a trumpet. At that sound
“a spirit arose among the people, that in the
eastern phrase, was like unto a trumpet in the
day of the whirlwind. Every person of every
rank, party, and denomination was convinced, that the
admission of Wood’s copper must prove fatal
to the Commonwealth. The papist, the fanatic,
the Tory, the Whig, all listed themselves volunteers
under the banners of M.B. Drapier, and were all
equally zealous to serve the Common cause.”
The present text of the first of the
Drapier’s letters is based on that given by
Sir W. Scott, carefully collated with two copies of
the first edition which differed from each other in
many particulars. One belonged to the late Colonel
F. Grant, and the other is in the British Museum.
It has also been read with the collection of the Drapier’s
Letters issued by the Drapier Club in 1725, with the
title, “Fraud Detected”; with the London
edition of “The Hibernian Patriot” (1730),
and with Faulkner’s text issued in his collected
edition of Swift’s Works in 1735.
[T.S.]
Concerning the
Brass Half-pence
Coined by
Mr. Woods,
WITH
A Design to have them Pass in this
KINGDOM.
Wherein is shewn the Power of the said PATENT,
the Value of the HALF-PENCE, and
how far every Person may be oblig’d
to take the
same in Payments, and how to behave in
Case
such an Attempt shou’d be made by
WOODS
or any other Person.
[Very Proper to be kept in every FAMILY.]
By
M.B. Drapier.
DUBLIN: Printed by J. Harding
in Molesworth’s-Court.
]
LETTER I.
TO THE TRADESMEN, SHOP-KEEPERS, FARMERS, AND COMMON-PEOPLE
IN GENERAL OF
IRELAND.BRETHREN, FRIENDS, COUNTRYMEN AND FELLOW-SUBJECTS,
What I intend now to say to you, is,
next to your duty to God, and the care of your salvation,
of the greatest concern to yourselves, and your children,
your bread and clothing, and every common necessary
of life entirely depend upon it. Therefore I
do most earnestly exhort you as men, as Christians,
as parents, and as lovers of your country, to read
this paper with the utmost attention, or get it read
to you by others; which that you may do at the less
expense, I have ordered the printer to sell it at
the lowest rate.
It is a great fault among you, that
when a person writes with no other intention than
to do you good, you will not be at the pains to read
his advices: One copy of this paper may serve
a dozen of you, which will be less than a farthing
a-piece. It is your folly that you have no common
or general interest in your view, not even the wisest
among you, neither do you know or enquire, or care
who are your friends, or who are your enemies.
About three years ago, a little
book was written, to advise all people to wear the
manufactures of this our own dear country: It had
no other design, said nothing against the King or Parliament,
or any man, yet the POOR PRINTER was prosecuted two
years, with the utmost violence, and even some WEAVERS
themselves, for whose sake it was written, being upon
the JURY, FOUND HIM GUILTY. This would be enough
to discourage any man from endeavouring to do you
good, when you will either neglect him or fly in his
face for his pains, and when he must expect only danger
to himself and loss of money, perhaps to his ruin.
However I cannot but warn you once
more of the manifest destruction before your eyes,
if you do not behave yourselves as you ought.
I will therefore first tell you the
plain story of the fact; and then I will lay before
you how you ought to act in common prudence, and according
to the laws of your country.
The fact is thus: It having been
many years since COPPER HALFPENCE OR FARTHINGS were
last coined in this kingdom, they have been for some
time very scarce, and many counterfeits passed
about under the name of raps, several applications
were made to England, that we might have liberty to
coin new ones, as in former times we did; but they
did not succeed. At last one Mr. Wood, a
mean ordinary man, a hardware dealer, procured a patentunder
his Majesty’s broad seal to coin fourscore and
ten thousand pounds in copper for this kingdom,
which patent however did not oblige any one here to
take them, unless they pleased. Now you must
know, that the halfpence and farthings in England
pass for very little more than they are worth.
And if you should beat them to pieces, and sell them
to the brazier you would not lose above a penny in
a shilling. But Mr. Wood made his halfpence of
such base metal, and so much smaller than the English
ones, that the brazier would not give you above a
penny of good money for a shilling of his; so that
this sum of fourscore and ten thousand pounds in good
gold and silver, must be given for trash that will
not be worth above eight or nine thousand pounds real
value. But this is not the worst, for Mr. Wood
when he pleases may by stealth send over another and
another fourscore and ten thousand pounds, and buy
all our goods for eleven parts in twelve, under the
value. For example, if a hatter sells a dozen
of hats for five shillings a-piece, which amounts
to three pounds, and receives the payment in Mr. Wood’s
coin, he really receives only the value of five shillings.
Perhaps you will wonder how such an
ordinary fellow as this Mr. Wood could have so much
interest as to get His Majesty’s broad seal for
so great a sum of bad money, to be sent to this poor
country, and that all the nobility and gentry here
could not obtain the same favour, and let us make
our own halfpence, as we used to do. Now I will
make that matter very plain. We are at a great
distance from the King’s court, and have nobody
there to solicit for us, although a great number of
lords and squires, whose estates are here, and are
our countrymen, spending all their lives and fortunes
there. But this same Mr. Wood was able to attend
constantly for his own interest; he is an Englishman
and had great friends, and it seems knew very well
where to give money, to those that would speak to
others that could speak to the King and could tell
a fair story. And His Majesty, and perhaps the
great lord or lords who advised him, might think it
was for our country’s good; and so, as the lawyers
express it, “the King was deceived in his grant,”
which often happens in all reigns. And I am sure
if His Majesty knew that such a patent, if it should
take effect according to the desire of Mr. Wood, would
utterly ruin this kingdom, which hath given such great
proofs of its loyalty, he would immediately recall
it, and perhaps shew his displeasure to somebody or
other. But “a word to the wise is enough.”
Most of you must have heard, with what anger our honourable
House of Commons received an account of this Wood’s
patent. There were several fine speeches made
upon it, and plain proofs that it was all A WICKED
CHEAT from the bottom to the top, and several smart
votes were printed, which that same Wood had the assurance
to answer likewise in print, and in so confident a
way, as if he were a better man than our whole Parliament
put together.
This Wood, as soon as his patent was
passed, or soon after, sends over a great many barrels
of these halfpence, to Cork and other sea-port towns,
and to get them off offered an hundred pounds in his
coin for seventy or eighty in silver. But the
collectors of the King’s customs very honestly
refused to take them, and so did almost everybody else.
And since the Parliament hath condemned them, and desired
the King that they might be stopped, all the kingdom
do abominate them.
But Wood is still working underhand
to force his halfpence upon us, and if he can by help
of his friends in England prevail so far as to get
an order that the commissioners and collectors of
the King’s money shall receive them, and that
the army is to be paid with them, then he thinks his
work shall be done. And this is the difficulty
you will be under in such a case. For the common
soldier when he goes to the market or alehouse will
offer this money, and if it be refused, perhaps he
will swagger and hector, and threaten to beat the
butcher or alewife, or take the goods by force, and
throw them the bad halfpence. In this and the
like cases, the shopkeeper or victualler, or any other
tradesman has no more to do, than to demand ten times
the price of his goods, if it is to be paid in Wood’s
money; for example, twenty-pence of that money for
a quart of ale, and so in all things else, and not
part with his goods till he gets the money.
For suppose you go to an alehouse
with that base money, and the landlord gives you a
quart for four of these halfpence, what must the victualler
do? His brewer will not be paid in that coin,
or if the brewer should be such a fool, the farmers
will not take it from them for their bere,
because they are bound by their leases to pay their
rents in good and lawful money of England, which this
is not, nor of Ireland neither, and the ’squire
their landlord will never be so bewitched to take such
trash for his land, so that it must certainly stop
somewhere or other, and wherever it stops it is the
same thing, and we are all undone.
The common weight of these halfpence
is between four and five to an ounce, suppose five,
then three shillings and fourpence will weigh a pound,
and consequently twenty shillings will weigh six pound
butter weight. Now there are many hundred farmers
who pay two hundred pound a year rent. Therefore
when one of these farmers comes with his half-year’s
rent, which is one hundred pound, it will be at least
six hundred pound weight, which is three horse load.
If a ’squire has a mind to come
to town to buy clothes and wine and spices for himself
and family, or perhaps to pass the winter here; he
must bring with him five or six horses loaden with
sacks as the farmers bring their corn; and when his
lady comes in her coach to our shops, it must be followed
by a car loaden with Mr. Wood’s money. And
I hope we shall have the grace to take it for no more
than it is worth.
They say ’Squire Conolly
has sixteen thousand pounds a year, now if he sends
for his rent to town, as it is likely he does, he must
have two hundred and forty horses to bring up his
half-year’s rent, and two or three great cellars
in his house for stowage. But what the bankers
will do I cannot tell. For I am assured, that
some great bankers keep by them forty thousand pounds
in ready cash to answer all payments, which sum, in
Mr. Wood’s money, would require twelve hundred
horses to carry it.
For my own part, I am already resolved
what to do; I have a pretty good shop of Irish stuffs
and silks, and instead of taking Mr. Wood’s bad
copper, I intend to truck with my neighbours the butchers,
and bakers, and brewers, and the rest, goods for goods,
and the little gold and silver I have, I will keep
by me like my heart’s blood till better times,
or till I am just ready to starve, and then I will
buy Mr. Wood’s money as my father did the brass
money in K. James’s time, who could buy
ten pound of it with a guinea, and I hope to get as
much for a pistole, and so purchase bread from those
who will be such fools as to sell it me.
These halfpence, if they once pass,
will soon be counterfeit, because it may be cheaply
done, the stuff is so base. The Dutch likewise
will probably do the same thing, and send them over
to us to pay for our goods. And Mr. Wood will
never be at rest but coin on: So that in some
years we shall have at least five times fourscore and
ten thousand pounds of this lumber. Now the current
money of this kingdom is not reckoned to be above
four hundred thousand pounds in all, and while there
is a silver sixpence left these blood-suckers will
never be quiet.
When once the kingdom is reduced to
such a condition, I will tell you what must be the
end: The gentlemen of estates will all turn off
their tenants for want of payment, because as I told
you before, the tenants are obliged by their leases
to pay sterling which is lawful current money of England;
then they will turn their own farmers, as too many
of them do already, run all into sheep where they
can, keeping only such other cattle as are necessary,
then they will be their own merchants and send their
wool and butter and hides and linen beyond sea for
ready money and wine and spices and silks. They
will keep only a few miserable cottiers. The farmers
must rob or beg, or leave their country. The
shopkeepers in this and every other town, must break
and starve: For it is the landed man that maintains
the merchant, and shopkeeper, and handicraftsman.
But when the ’squire turns farmer
and merchant himself, all the good money he gets from
abroad, he will hoard up or send for England, and
keep some poor tailor or weaver and the like in his
own house, who will be glad to get bread at any rate.
I should never have done if I were
to tell you all the miseries that we shall undergo
if we be so foolish and wicked as to take this CURSED
COIN. It would be very hard if all Ireland should
be put into one scale, and this sorry fellow Wood
into the other, that Mr. Wood should weigh down this
whole kingdom, by which England gets above a million
of good money every year clear into their pockets,
and that is more than the English do by all the world
besides.
But your great comfort is, that as
His Majesty’s patent does not oblige you to
take this money, so the laws have not given the crown
a power of forcing the subjects to take what money
the King pleases: For then by the same reason
we might be bound to take pebble-stones or cockle-shells
or stamped leather for current coin, if ever we should
happen to live under an ill prince, who might likewise
by the same power make a guinea pass for ten pounds,
a shilling for twenty shillings, and so on, by which
he would in a short time get all the silver and gold
of the kingdom into his own hands, and leave us nothing
but brass or leather or what he pleased. Neither
is anything reckoned more cruel or oppressive in the
French government than their common practice of calling
in all their money after they have sunk it very low,
and then coining it anew at a much higher value, which
however is not the thousandth part so wicked as this
abominable project of Mr. Wood. For the French
give their subjects silver for silver and gold for
gold, but this fellow will not so much as give us
good brass or copper for our gold and silver, nor
even a twelfth part of their worth.
Having said thus much, I will now
go on to tell you the judgments of some great lawyers
in this matter, whom I fee’d on purpose for your
sakes, and got their opinions under their hands, that
I might be sure I went upon good grounds.
A famous law-book, called “The
Mirror of Justice," discoursing of the articles
(or laws) ordained by our ancient kings declares the
law to be as follows: “It was ordained
that no king of this realm should change, impair or
amend the money or make any other money than of gold
or silver without the assent of all the counties,”
that is, as my Lord Coke says, without the assent
of Parliament.
This book is very ancient, and of
great authority for the time in which it was wrote,
and with that character is often quoted by that great
lawyer my Lord Coke. By the law of England, the
several metals are divided into lawful or true metal
and unlawful or false metal, the former comprehends
silver or gold; the latter all baser metals: That
the former is only to pass in payments appears by
an act of Parliament made the twentieth year of
Edward the First, called the “Statute concerning
the Passing of Pence,” which I give you here
as I got it translated into English, for some of our
laws at that time, were, as I am told writ in Latin:
“Whoever in buying or selling presumeth to refuse
an halfpenny or farthing of lawful money, bearing the
stamp which it ought to have, let him be seized on
as a contemner of the King’s majesty, and cast
into prison.”
By this statute, no person is to be
reckoned a contemner of the King’s majesty,
and for that crime to be committed to prison; but he
who refuses to accept the King’s coin made of
lawful metal, by which, as I observed before, silver
and gold only are intended.
That this is the true construction
of the act, appears not only from the plain meaning
of the words, but from my Lord Coke’s observation
upon it. “By this act” (says he)
“it appears, that no subject can be forced to
take in buying or selling or other payments, any money
made but of lawful metal; that is, of silver or gold."
The law of England gives the King
all mines of gold and silver, but not the mines of
other metals, the reason of which prerogative or power,
as it is given by my Lord Coke is, because money
can be made of gold and silver, but not of other metals.
Pursuant to this opinion halfpence
and farthings were anciently made of silver, which
is most evident from the act of Parliament of Henry
the 4th. cha. by which it is enacted as follows:
“Item, for the great scarcity that is at present
within the realm of England of halfpence and farthings
of silver, it is ordained and established that the
third part of all the money of silver plate which shall
be brought to the bullion, shall be made in halfpence
and farthings.” This shews that by the
word “halfpenny” and “farthing”
of lawful money in that statute concerning the passing
of pence, are meant a small coin in halfpence and
farthings of silver.
This is further manifest from the
statute of the ninth year of Edward the 3d. cha. which enacts, “That no sterling halfpenny
or farthing be molten for to make vessel, nor any
other thing by the goldsmiths, nor others, upon forfeiture
of the money so molten” (or melted).
By another act in this King’s
reign black money was not to be current in England,
and by an act made in the eleventh year of his reign
cha. galley halfpence were not to pass, what kind
of coin these were I do not know, but I presume they
were made of base metal, and that these acts were
no new laws, but farther declarations of the old laws
relating to the coin.
Thus the law stands in relation to
coin, nor is there any example to the contrary, except
one in Davis’s Reports, who tells us that
in the time of Tyrone’s rebellion Queen Elizabeth
ordered money of mixed metal to be coined in the Tower
of London, and sent over hither for payment of the
army, obliging all people to receive it and commanding
that all silver money should be taken only as bullion,
that is, for as much as it weighed. Davis tells
us several particulars in this matter too long here
to trouble you with, and that the privy-council of
this kingdom obliged a merchant in England to receive
this mixed money for goods transmitted hither.
But this proceeding is rejected by
all the best lawyers as contrary to law, the Privy-council
here having no such power. And besides it is to
be considered, that the Queen was then under great
difficulties by a rebellion in this kingdom assisted
from Spain, and whatever is done in great exigences
and dangerous times should never be an example to
proceed by in seasons of peace and quietness.
I will now, my dear friends to save
you the trouble, set before you in short, what the
law obliges you to do, and what it does not oblige
you to.
First, You are obliged to take all
money in payments which is coined by the King and
is of the English standard or weight, provided it be
of gold or silver.
Secondly, You are not obliged to take
any money which is not of gold or silver, no not the
halfpence, or farthings of England, or of any other
country, and it is only for convenience, or ease, that
you are content to take them, because the custom of
coining silver halfpence and farthings hath long been
left off, I will suppose on account of their being
subject to be lost.
Thirdly, Much less are you obliged
to take those vile halfpence of that same Wood, by
which you must lose almost eleven-pence in every shilling.
Therefore my friends, stand to it
one and all, refuse this filthy trash. It is
no treason to rebel against Mr. Wood. His Majesty
in his patent obliges nobody to take these halfpence,
our gracious prince hath no so ill advisers about
him; or if he had, yet you see the laws have not left
it in the King’s power, to force us to take any
coin but what is lawful, of right standard gold and
silver, therefore you have nothing to fear.
And let me in the next place apply
myself particularly to you who are the poor sort of
tradesmen, perhaps you may think you will not be so
great losers as the rich, if these halfpence should
pass, because you seldom see any silver, and your
customers come to your shops or stalls with nothing
but brass, which you likewise find hard to be got,
but you may take my word, whenever this money gains
footing among you, you will be utterly undone; if
you carry these halfpence to a shop for tobacco or
brandy, or any other thing you want, the shopkeeper
will advance his goods accordingly, or else he must
break, and leave the key under the door. Do you
think I will sell you a yard of tenpenny stuff for
twenty of Mr. Wood’s halfpence? No, not
under two hundred at least, neither will I be at the
trouble of counting, but weigh them in a lump; I will
tell you one thing further, that if Mr. Wood’s
project should take, it will ruin even our beggars;
For when I give a beggar an halfpenny, it will quench
his thirst, or go a good way to fill his belly, but
the twelfth part of a halfpenny will do him no more
service than if I should give him three pins out of
my sleeve.
In short these halfpence are like
“the accursed thing, which” as the Scripture
tells us, “the children of Israel were forbidden
to touch,” they will run about like the plague
and destroy every one who lays his hands upon them.
I have heard scholars talk of a man who told a king
that he had invented a way to torment people by putting
them into a bull of brass with fire under it, but
the prince put the projector first into his own brazen
bull to make the experiment; this very much resembles
the project of Mr. Wood, and the like of this may possibly
be Mr. Wood’s fate, that the brass he contrived
to torment this kingdom with, may prove his own torment,
and his destruction at last.
N.B. The author of this paper
is informed by persons who have made it their business
to be exact in their observations on the true value
of these halfpence, that any person may expect to
get a quart of twopenny ale for thirty-six of them.
I desire all persons may keep this
paper carefully by them to refresh their memories
whenever they shall have farther notice of Mr. Wood’s
halfpence, or any other the like imposture.