I must now relate how he robbed Byzantium
and other cities of their ornaments. In the first
place he resolved to humiliate the lawyers. He
deprived them of all the fees, which, after they had
finished their case, were considerable, and enriched
them and increased their distinction. He ordered
that litigants should come to an agreement upon oath,
which brought the lawyers into contempt and insignificance.
After he had seized the estates of the Senators and
other families reputed wealthy, in Byzantium and throughout
the Empire, the profession had little to do, for the
citizens no longer possessed property worth disputing
about. Thus, of the numerous and famous orators
who once composed this order there remained only a
few, who were everywhere despised and lived in the
greatest poverty, finding that their profession brought
them nothing but insult. He also caused physicians
and professors of the liberal arts to be deprived of
the necessaries of life. He cut off from them
all the supplies which former emperors had attached
to these professions, and which were paid out of the
State funds. Further, he had no scruple about
transferring to the public funds all the revenues
which the inhabitants of the cities had devoted either
to public purposes or for providing entertainments.
From that time no attention was paid to physicians
or professors; no one ventured to trouble himself
about the public buildings; there were no public lights
in the cities, or any enjoyments for the inhabitants;
the performances in the theatres and hippodromes
and the combats of wild beasts, in which Theodora had
been bred and brought up, were entirely discontinued.
He afterwards suppressed public exhibitions in Byzantium,
to save the usual State contribution, to the ruin
of an almost countless multitude who found their means
of support in these entertainments. Their life,
both in public and private, became sad and dejected
and utterly joyless, as if some misfortune had fallen
upon them from Heaven. Nothing was spoken of
in conversation at home, in the streets, or in the
churches, except misfortune and suffering. Such
was the state of the cities.
I have still something important to
mention. Every year two consuls were appointed one
at Rome, the other at Byzantium. Whoever was
advanced to that dignity was expected to expend more
than twenty centenars of gold upon the public.
This sum was to a small extent furnished by the consuls
themselves, while the greater part was due to the
liberality of the Emperor. This money was distributed
amongst those whom I have mentioned, above all to
the most necessitous, and principally to those employed
upon the stage, which materially increased the comfort
of the citizens. But, since the accession of
Justinian, the elections never took place at the proper
time; sometimes one consul remained in office for
several years, and at last people never even dreamed
of a fresh appointment. This reduced all to the
greatest distress; since the Emperor no longer granted
the usual assistance to his subjects, and at the same
time deprived them of what they had by every means
in his power.
I think I have given a sufficient
account of the manner in which this destroyer swallowed
up the property of the members of the Senate and deprived
them all of their substance, whether publicly or privately.
I also think that I have said enough concerning the
fraudulent accusations which he made use of, in order
to get possession of the property of other families
which were reputed to be wealthy. Lastly, I have
described the wrongs he inflicted upon the soldiers
and servants of those in authority and the militia
in the palace; upon countrymen, the possessors and
proprietors of estates, and professors of the arts
and sciences; upon merchants, shipmasters and sailors;
mechanics, artisans, and retail dealers; those who
gained their livelihood by performing upon the stage;
in a word, upon all who were affected by the misery
of these. I must now speak of his treatment of
the poor, the lower classes, the indigent, and the
sick and infirm. I will then go on to speak of
his treatment of the priests.
At first, as has been said, he got
all the shops into his own hands, and having established
monopolies of all the most necessary articles of life,
exacted from his subjects more than three times their
value. But if I were to enter into the details
of all these monopolies, I should never finish my
narrative, for they are innumerable.
He imposed a perpetual and most severe
tax upon bread, which the artisans, the poor, and
infirm were compelled to purchase. He demanded
from this commodity a revenue of three centenars
of gold every year, and those poor wretches were obliged
to support themselves upon bread full of dust, for
the Emperor did not blush to carry his avarice to
this extent. Seizing upon this as an excuse, the
superintendents of the markets, eager to fill their
own pockets, in a short time acquired great wealth,
and, in spite of the cheapness of food, reduced the
poor to a state of artificial and unexpected famine;
for they were not allowed to import corn from any
other parts, but were obliged to eat bread purchased
in the city.
One of the city aqueducts had broken,
and a considerable portion of the water destined for
the use of the inhabitants was lost. Justinian,
however, took no notice of it, being unwilling to incur
any expense for repairs, although a great crowd continually
thronged round the fountains, and all the baths had
been shut. Nevertheless, he expended vast sums
without any reason or sense upon buildings on the seashore,
and also built everywhere throughout the suburbs, as
if the palaces, in which their predecessors had always
been content to live, were no longer suitable for
himself and Theodora; so that it was not merely parsimony,
but a desire for the destruction of human life, that
prevented him from repairing the aqueduct, for no one,
from most ancient times, had ever shown himself more
eager than Justinian to amass wealth, and at the same
time to spend it in a most wasteful and extravagant
manner. Thus this Emperor struck at the poorest
and most miserable of his subjects through two most
necessary articles of food bread and water,
by making the one difficult to procure, and the other
too dear for them to buy.
It was not only the poor of Byzantium,
however, that he harassed in this manner, but, as
I will presently mention, the inhabitants of several
other cities. When Theodoric had made himself
master of Italy, in order to preserve some trace of
the old constitution, he permitted the praetorian
guards to remain in the palace and continued their
daily allowance. These soldiers were very numerous.
There were the Silentiarii, the Domestici, and the
Scholares, about whom there was nothing military except
the name, and their salary was hardly sufficient to
live upon. Theodoric also ordered that their children
and descendants should have the reversion of this.
To the poor, who lived near the church of Peter the
Apostle, he distributed every year 3,000 bushels of
corn out of the public stores. All continued to
receive these donations until the arrival of Alexander
Forficula in Italy. He resolved to deprive
them of it immediately; and, when the Emperor was
informed of this, he approved of his conduct, and treated
Alexander with still greater honour. During his
journey, Alexander treated the Greeks in the following
manner: The peasants of the district near
the pass of Thermopylae had long manned the fortress,
and, each in turn, mounted guard over the wall which
blocks the pass, whenever there seemed any likelihood
of an invasion of the barbarians. But Alexander,
on his arrival, pretended that it was to the interest
of the Peloponnesians not to leave the protection of
the pass to the peasants. He established a garrison
of about 2,000 soldiers, who were not paid out of
the public funds, but by each of the cities in Greece.
On this pretext, he transferred to the public treasury
all the revenues of these towns which were intended
for public purposes or to cover the expenses of shows
and entertainments. He pretended that it was
to be employed for the support of the soldiers, and
in consequence, from that time, no public buildings
or other objects of utility were erected or promoted
either in Athens or throughout Greece. Justinian,
however, hastened to give his sanction to all the
acts of Forficula.
We must now speak of the poor of Alexandria.
Amongst the lawyers of that city was one Hephaestus,
who, having been appointed governor, suppressed popular
disturbances by the terror he inspired, but at the
same time reduced the citizens to the greatest distress.
He immediately established a monopoly of all wares,
which he forbade other merchants to sell. He
reserved everything for himself alone, sold everything
himself, and fixed the price by the capricious exercise
of his authority. Consequently, the city was in
the greatest distress from want of provisions; the
poor no longer had a sufficient supply of what was
formerly sold at a low rate, and especially felt the
difficulty of obtaining bread; for the governor alone
bought up all the corn that came from Egypt, and did
not allow anyone else to purchase even so much as
a bushel; and in this manner, he taxed the loaves
and put upon them what price he pleased. By this
means he amassed an enormous fortune, and was likewise
careful to satisfy the greed of the Emperor.
So great was the terror inspired by Hephaestus, that
the people of Alexandria endured their ill-treatment
in silence; and the Emperor, out of gratitude for
the money which flowed into his exchequer from that
quarter, conceived a great affection for Hephaestus.
The latter, in order to secure in a still greater degree
the favour of the Emperor, carried out the following
plan. When Diocletian became Emperor of the Romans,
he ordered a yearly distribution of corn to be made
to the necessitous poor of Alexandria; and the people,
settling its distribution amongst themselves, transmitted
the right to their descendants. Hephaestus deprived
the necessitous of 2,000,000 bushels yearly, and deposited
it in the imperial granaries, declaring, in his despatch
to the Emperor, that this grant of corn had previously
been made in a manner that was neither just nor in
conformity with the interests of the state. The
Emperor approved of his conduct and became more attached
to him than ever. The Alexandrians, whose hopes
of existence depended upon this distribution, felt
the cruelty bitterly, especially at the time of their
distress.