THE CONSTITUTIONAL QUESTION
BY GEORGE CAVE, K.C., M.P.
INTRODUCTORY
Few things are more remarkable in
the Parliamentary history of the Home Rule movement
than the complete absence from the counsels of the
English advocates of Home Rule of any definite and
settled policy as to the form of self-government to
be offered to Ireland, and their consequent oscillation
between proposals radically differing from one another.
Since the “new departure” initiated by
Davitt and Devoy in 1878, it has been the deliberate
practice of Irish Nationalists to abstain from defining
the Nationalist demand and to ask in general terms
for “self-government,” doubtless with
the object of attracting the support of all who favour
any change which could be described by that very elastic
term. Such a policy has its advantages. But
confusion of thought, however favourable to popular
agitation, is a disadvantage when the moment for legislation
arrives; and uncertainty as to the aim goes far to
explain the vacillation in Home Rule policy.
Mr. Gladstone’s Home Rule Bill
of 1886 would have given to Ireland the substance
of “responsible” or colonial self-government,
subject only to certain reservations and restrictions,
the value of which will be considered later in this
chapter, and would have excluded the Irish members
and representative peers from the Parliament of the
United Kingdom. By the Bill of 1893 the reservations
and restrictions were increased, and representatives
of Ireland were to be permitted to sit at Westminster by
the Bill as introduced for some purposes, and by the
Bill as passed by the House of Commons for all purposes.
After the defeat of this second Bill,
a “cold fit” appears to have seized the
Liberal Party. Lord Rosebery, in 1894, declared
that before Home Rule could be carried England, as
the predominant partner, must be convinced. Sir
Edward Grey in 1905 declared that his party on its
return to power would “go on with Sir Anthony
MacDonnell’s policy,” which he rightly
described as a policy of large administrative reforms;
and Mr. Asquith “associated himself entirely
and unreservedly with every word” of Sir Edward
Grey’s speech. Accordingly the Irish Council
Bill proposed by Mr. Asquith’s Government in
1907 was purely a measure of devolution, certain administrative
functions only being put under the control of an Irish
Council, subject to the veto of the Lord Lieutenant,
and the whole legislative power remaining in the Parliament
of the United Kingdom. This proposal, having
been condemned by a National Convention at Dublin,
was incontinently withdrawn.
In the years succeeding this fiasco
the Liberal policy for Ireland appeared to be at the
mercy of shifting winds. For some time Liberal
speakers contented themselves with vague declarations
in favour of Federalism or “Home Rule all round” phrases
which may mean much or little according to the sense
in which they are used. More recently an able
writer, while admitting that “there is no
public opinion in Ireland as to the form of the Irish
Constitution,” has argued in a work of 350 pages
in favour of the grant to Ireland of full legislative,
administrative and financial autonomy; while a member
of the Government declared that fiscal autonomy
for all practical purposes means separation and the
disintegration of the United Kingdom. In a publication
recently issued by a committee of Liberals, comprising
several members of the present Government, two
views directly contrary to one another are put forward,
one writer arguing for a devolution to an Irish body
of “definite and defined powers only,”
and another for the grant of the widest possible form
of Home Rule and the exclusion from Westminster of
all Irish representation. The latest official
pronouncements indicate that the Government have it
in their minds to revert to the Gladstonian form of
Home Rule; but even now no one outside the Cabinet,
and possibly few inside that inner circle, would venture
on a confident prophecy even as to the broad lines
of the measure which in a few days may be submitted
to Parliament as representing the urgent and considered
demand of public opinion.
Franklin said truly that
“those who govern,
having much business on their hands, do not
generally like to take
the trouble of considering and carrying into
execution new projects.”
But surely on a question of such vital
moment to the Empire as the revision of the constitution
of the United Kingdom, the bases, if not the details,
of the contemplated change are deserving of prolonged
consideration and even of some public and ordered discussion.
The British North America Act, 1867, by which the
relation of the Dominion of Canada to its provinces
is regulated, was the result, not only of years of
preliminary debate in the provincial Legislatures and
elsewhere, but of a formal conference at Quebec in
1864, followed by the appointment of delegates to
confer with the Imperial Government on the matter.
In Australia the proposal for union, agitated at intervals
since 1846, was canvassed in every detail at inter-colonial
Conferences or Conventions in 1883, in 1891, and in
1897-8, as well as in the several colonial Legislatures,
before it was embodied in the Australia Constitution
Act, 1900. And although in the case of South Africa,
owing to the urgency of the question of union, the
time occupied in the discussion was less than in the
other great dominions, yet in the Convention of 1908-9
the best brains in the country were occupied for months
in considering every detail of the proposal for union
before it was submitted to the Colonial and Imperial
Parliaments for their sanction. And yet in the
Mother Country, where centuries of military and political
conflict have given us the Union, it is considered
that a few weeks’ consideration by a committee
of the Cabinet, without advice from independent constitutional
experts, and without formal consultation even
with the Government’s own supporters outside
the Ministry, is sufficient to determine both the
general form and the details of a proposal for its
dissolution.
In the confusion so engendered it
may be useful to consider in some detail the different
proposals which have been or may be made under the
name of Home Rule, their special qualities and dangers,
and the results to which they may severally lead.
RESPONSIBLE GOVERNMENT.
A proposal to give to Ireland full
“responsible” government, without any
other limitations than such as are imposed on our self-governing
Colonies, would find few supporters in this country.
Under such a constitution an Irish Government would
have power to forbid or restrict recruiting for the
Imperial forces in Ireland, and to raise and train
a force of its own. It might establish or subsidise
a religion, make education wholly denominational,
levy customs duties on imports from Great Britain
and give fiscal advantages to a foreign power, confiscate
or transfer property without payment, and deprive individuals
of nationality, franchise, liberty, or life without
process of law. However improbable some of these
contingencies may appear, it is right on a matter
of so much moment to consider possibilities and not
probabilities only. Such powers as these could
not without serious risk be conceded to any part of
the kingdom, and in the case of Ireland there would
be a special danger in granting them to a popularly
elected body.
In the first place, the national safety
would be involved. Englishmen were at one time
too fond of saying that the great Colonies might, if
they chose, sever the link which binds them to the
Mother Country. Happily, in their case, no such
catastrophe need now be considered. But it would
be folly to shut our eyes to the fact that to many
Irishmen national independence appears to be the only
goal worth striving for. If the concession of
full responsible government should be followed (at
whatever interval) by an assertion of complete independence,
we may assume that Great Britain would follow the
example of Federal America and re-establish the Union
by force of arms, but at how great a cost! Those
who deny the possibility of a serious movement towards
separation would do well to remember Mr. Gladstone’s
reference to the position of Norway and Sweden,
then united under one crown:
“Let us look to those two countries,
neither of them very large, but yet countries
which every Englishman and every Scotchman must rejoice
to claim his kin I mean the Scandinavian
countries of Sweden and Norway. Immediately
after the great war the Norwegians were ready
to take sword in hand to prevent their coming under
the domination of Sweden. But the Powers
of Europe undertook the settlement of that question,
and they united those countries upon a footing
of strict legislative independence and co-equality....
And yet with two countries so united, what has
been the effect? Not discord, not convulsions,
not danger to peace, not hatred, not aversion,
but a constantly growing sympathy; and every man who
knows their condition knows that I speak the truth
when I say that in every year that passes the
Norwegians and the Swedes are more and more feeling
themselves to be the children of a common country,
united by a tie which never is to be broken.”
The tie was broken within twenty years.
It may be that the Nationalist leaders,
or some of them, do not desire separation; but it
by no means follows that a concession of their demands
would not lead to that result. Franklin, in 1774,
had an interview with Chatham, in which he says
“I assured him that, having more
than once travelled almost from one end of the
continent (of America) to the other, and kept a great
variety of company, eating, drinking, and conversing
with them freely, I never had heard in any conversation
from any person, drunk or sober, the least expression
of a wish for a separation, or a hint that such
a thing would be advantageous to America."
And yet independence came within ten years.
In the case of the United Kingdom
there is no need to consider in detail how serious
would be the effects naval, military, and
economic of separation, for the gravity
of such a contingency is admitted by all. Admiral
Mahan, the American naval expert, writes that
“the ambition of the Irish separatists,
realised, might be even more threatening to the
national life of Great Britain than the secession
of the South was to that of the American Union....
The instrument for such action in the shape of
an independent Parliament could not safely be
trusted even to avowed friends.”
Some Home Rulers are able to
“rise superior
to the philosophy, as fallacious in fact as it is
base and cowardly in
purpose, which sets the safety of a great
nation above the happiness
and prosperity of a small one,"
but to less lofty souls it appears
that the safety of the nation is paramount, and that
upon it depends the prosperity of each of its component
parts.
In the next place, in considering
whether complete “colonial” self-government
can be conceded to Ireland, it must not be forgotten
that the island is bi-racial, that the two races differ
widely in character, in politics, and in religion,
and that the differences are apt to find vent in violent
conflict or secret attacks. Further, Ireland
has for generations been the scene of a revolt against
one particular species of property, the ownership
of land; and although under the operation of the Land
Purchase Acts this cause of conflict tends to abate,
it still breaks out from time to time in the form of
cattle drives and attacks on “land grabbers."
Hitherto we have, broadly speaking, kept the peace.
That we should now forsake this duty, and, washing
our hands of Ireland, leave the Protestant and the
landowner, at or small, to his fate is unthinkable.
In connection with the question last-mentioned
it may be necessary at some time to consider how far
it is the constitutional right of this country to
impose upon the minority in Ireland the new obligations
implied in a grant to the whole island of colonial
Home Rule. It may be that the Imperial Parliament
can disallow the claim of a section of the population
of Ireland to remain subject to its own control.
But it is one thing to reject the allegiance of a
community, it is quite another thing forcibly to transfer
that allegiance to a practically independent legislature;
and this is especially the case when the transfer may
involve the use against a loyal population of coercion
in its extreme form.
CHECKS AND SAFEGUARDS.
In every formal proposal for Home
Rule in Ireland, weight has been given to the above
considerations, and attempts have been made to meet
them by qualifying the grant of responsible Government.
The qualifications suggested have taken the form of
(a) the reservation of certain powers to the
Imperial Parliament, or (b) the restriction
of the powers granted to the Irish legislature by
prohibiting their exercise in certain specific ways,
or (c) the provision of some form of Imperial
veto or control. It is important to consider whether
and how far such checks or “safeguards”
are likely to prove effective and lasting.
The “safeguards” proposed
by the Government of Ireland Bill, 1886, were somewhat
extended by the Bill of 1893; and the proposals shortly
to be submitted to Parliament, so far as they can
be gathered from recent speeches of Ministers, will
not in this respect differ materially from those contained
in the latter Bill. It will therefore be convenient
to take as a basis for discussion the provisions of
the Bill of 1893, as passed by the House of Commons.
The Bill of 1893, after stating in
a preamble that it was “expedient that without
impairing or restricting the supreme authority of
Parliament an Irish Legislature should be created for
such purposes in Ireland as in this Act mentioned,”
proposed to set up in Ireland a Legislature consisting
of the Sovereign and two Houses, namely a Legislative
Council of 48 members to be returned under a restricted
franchise by the Irish counties and the boroughs of
Dublin and Belfast, and a Legislative Assembly of
103 members to be returned by the existing parliamentary
constituencies in Ireland. A Bill introduced into
the Irish Legislature was to pass both Houses; but
in the event of disagreement the proposals of the
Legislative Assembly were to be submitted, after a
dissolution or a delay of two years, to a joint Session
of the two Houses. The executive power was to
remain in the Crown, aided and advised by an Irish
Ministry (called an Executive Committee of the Privy
Council of Ireland), and the assent of the Crown to
Irish legislation was to be given or withheld on the
advice of this Executive Committee subject to any
instructions given by the Sovereign.
The specific reservations and restrictions
were contained in clauses 3 and 4 of the Bill, which
were as follows:
“3. The Irish
Legislature shall not have power to make laws in
respect of the following
matters or any of them:
“(1) The Crown,
or the succession to the Crown, or a Regency; or
the Lord Lieutenant
as representative of the Crown; or
“(2) The making of peace or war
or matters arising from a state of war; or the
regulation of the conduct of any portion of Her Majesty’s
subjects during the existence of hostilities between
foreign States with which Her Majesty is at peace,
in respect of such hostilities; or
“(3) Navy, army, militia, volunteers,
and any other military forces, or the defence
of the realm, or forts, permanent military camps,
magazines, arsenals, dockyards, and other needful
buildings, or any places purchased for the erection
thereof; or
“(4) Authorising
either the carrying or using of arms for military
purposes, or the formation
of associations for drill or practice
in the use of arms for
military purposes; or
“(5) Treaties or any relations
with foreign States or the relations between
different parts of Her Majesty’s dominions, or
offences connected with such treaties or relations,
or procedure connected with the extradition of
criminals under any treaty; or
“(6) Dignities
or titles of honour; or
“(7) Treason,
treason-felony, alienage, aliens as such, or
naturalisation; or
“(8) Trade with
any place out of Ireland; or quarantine, or
navigation, including
merchant shipping (except as respects inland
waters and local health
or harbour regulations); or
“(9) Lighthouses, buoys, or beacons
within the meaning of the Merchant Shipping Act,
1854, and the Acts amending the same (except
so far as they can consistently with any general Act
of Parliament be constructed or maintained by
a local harbour authority); or
“(10) Coinage;
legal tender; or any change in the standard of
weights and measures;
or
“(11) Trade marks,
designs, merchandise marks, copyright, or
patent rights.
“Provided always, that nothing
in this section shall prevent the passing of
any Irish Act to provide for any charges imposed by
Act of Parliament, or to prescribe conditions
regulating importation from any place outside
Ireland for the sole purpose of preventing the
introduction of any contagious disease.
“It is hereby declared that the
exceptions from the powers of the Irish Legislature
contained in this section are set forth and enumerated
for greater certainty, and not so as to restrict the
generality of the limitation imposed in the previous
section on the powers of the Irish Legislature.
“Any law made
in contravention of this section shall be void.
“4. The powers
of the Irish Legislature shall not extend to the
making of any law
“(1) Respecting
the establishment or endowment of religion,
whether directly or
indirectly, or prohibiting the free exercise
thereof; or
“(2) Imposing any disability,
or conferring any privilege, advantage, or benefit,
on account of religious belief, or raising or
appropriating directly or indirectly, save as heretofore,
any public revenue for any religious purpose,
or for the benefit of the holder of any religious
office as such; or
“(3) Diverting
the property, or, without its consent, altering the
constitution of any
religious body; or
“(4) Abrogating
or prejudicially affecting the right to establish
or maintain any place
of denominational education, or any
denominational institution
or charity; or
“(5) Whereby there may be established
or endowed out of public funds any theological
professorship, or any university or college in
which the conditions set out in the University of Dublin
Tests Acts, 1873, are not observed; or
“(6) Prejudicially
affecting the right of any child to attend a
school receiving public
money without attending the religious
instruction at that
school; or
“(7) Directly or indirectly imposing
any disability or conferring any privilege, benefit,
or advantage upon any subject of the Crown on
account of his parentage or place of birth, or of the
place where any part of his business is carried
on, or upon any corporation or institution constituted
or existing by virtue of the law of some part
of the Queen’s dominions, and carrying on operations
in Ireland, on account of the persons by whom or in
whose favour, or the place in which any of its
operations are carried on; or
“(8) Whereby any person may be
deprived of life, liberty, or property without
due process of law in accordance with settled principles
and precedents, or may be denied the equal protection
of the laws, or whereby private property may be
taken without just compensation; or
“(9) Whereby any existing corporation
incorporated by Royal Charter or by any local
or general Act of Parliament may, unless it consents,
or the leave of Her Majesty is first obtained on address
from the two Houses of the Irish Legislature, be deprived
of its rights, privileges, or property without
due process of law in accordance with settled
principles and precedents, and so far as respects
property without just compensation. Provided nothing
in this sub-section shall prevent the Irish Legislature
from dealing with any public department, municipal
corporation, or local authority, or with any
corporation administering for public purposes
taxes, rates, cess, dues, or tolls, so far as concerns
the same. Any law made in contravention of
this section shall be void.”
The power to impose taxation other
than duties of custom and excise was to be transferred,
subject to a short delay as to existing taxes and to
a special provision in respect of taxes for war expenditure,
to the Irish Legislature (clause II). Two judges
of the Supreme Court in Ireland, to be called “Exchequer
Judges,” were to be appointed under the Great
Seal of the United Kingdom, and to be removable only
on an address from the Imperial Parliament; and proceedings
relating to the reserved powers or to the customs
or excise duties were to be determined by such judges
(clause 19). Appeals from the Courts in Ireland
were to lie to the Judicial Committee of the Imperial
Privy Council (clause 21); and any question as to
the powers of the Irish Legislature could be referred
to the same Committee (clause 22). The Royal Irish
Constabulary and Dublin Metropolitan Police Force
were gradually to disappear, and police matters to
be regulated by the Irish Legislature and Executive
(clause 29). The Irish Legislature was to be
prohibited from passing land legislation for a period
of three years (clause 34).
As to these proposals the first observation
that occurs is that, in addition to the matters proposed
to be reserved, there are others in which legislative
uniformity throughout the kingdom is greatly to be
desired. To mention but a few such matters, questions
of status, contract and succession, of international
trade and navigation, of the regulation of railways
and of industrial labour, and of the criminal law,
should not be differently determined in different parts
of the kingdom; and as life becomes more complex,
the number of subjects in which diversity of laws
is a hindrance continues to increase.
In the next place, it is to be noted
that the checks proposed affect legislation only and
not administration. If the Bill of 1893 or any
similar Bill should become law, the whole executive
power in Ireland will be in an Irish Ministry responsible
to an Irish Assembly; and it is obvious that many
of the wrongs against which the restrictive clauses
of the Bill were directed may be inflicted by administrative
act or omission as effectively as by legislation.
To quote a work of authority
“An independent Irish Executive
will possess immense power. It will be able
by mere administrative action or inaction, without
passing a single law which infringes any restriction
to be imposed by the Irish Government Act, 1893,
to effect a revolution. Let us consider for
a moment a few of the things which the Irish Cabinet
might do if it chose. It might confine all
political, administrative, or judicial appointments
to Nationalists, and thus exclude Loyalists from
all positions of public trust. It might place
the bench, the magistracy, the police, wholly
in the hands of Catholics; it might, by encouragement
of athletic clubs where the Catholic population were
trained to the use of arms, combined with the rigorous
suppression of every Protestant association suspected,
rightly or not, of preparing resistance to the
Parliament at Dublin, bring about the arming
of Catholic, and the disarming of Protestant, Ireland,
and, at the same time, raise a force as formidable
to England as an openly enrolled Irish army.
But the mere inaction of the executive might
in many spheres produce greater results than active
unfairness. The refusal of the police for the
enforcement of evictions would abolish rent throughout
the country. And the same result might be
attained by a more moderate course. Irish Ministers
might in practice draw a distinction between ‘good’
landlords and ‘bad’ landlords, and
might grant the aid of the police for the collection
of ‘reasonable,’ though refusing it for
the collection of ‘excessive,’ rents.”
Irish Ministers might even refuse
actively to oppose the “moral claim” of
the Irish Catholics to the use of the cathedrals and
of the accumulated capital of the Irish Church.
To contemplate the possibility of
action or calculated inaction of the character above
described is not to attribute to Irishmen any special
measure of original sin. In every case where the
executive power is divorced from the ultimate legislative
authority such divergencies are likely to recur; and
more than one instance may be found in our own recent
history. In 1859 the Canadian Government warned
the Home Government that any attempt to interfere
with the customs policy of the Dominion was inadmissible,
unless the home authorities were prepared to undertake
the responsibility of administering the whole government
of Canada. The Home Government gave way.
In 1878 the Governor of Cape Colony proposed to place
the colonial forces under the control of the officer
commanding the Imperial forces. The Cape Government
resisted, and refused to resign; and eventually the
Governor, on the advice of the Home Government, dismissed
his ministers. In this case a change of government
occurred after the general election, but in the end
the claim put forward by the Imperial authorities
had to be withdrawn. In 1906 the Natal Government
proclaimed martial law, and ordered the execution
of twelve natives on charges of murder. The Imperial
Government intervened, and suggested the suspension
of the order pending further consideration. The
Natal Ministry immediately resigned; and as there was
no chance of the formation of a new Government, the
Imperial authorities hastily withdrew.
Differences have arisen even on so
grave a matter as the succession to the throne.
The union of England and Scotland in 1707 was preceded
and hastened by the so-called Act of Security, by
which the Scottish Estates asserted the right to name
a successor to the throne of Scotland, who should
not (except under certain specified conditions) be
the person designated as sovereign by the English
law. And during the illness of King George III.
in the year 1788, Grattan, in defiance of the views
of Pitt and of the majority in both Houses of the
Imperial Parliament, carried in the Irish Parliament
an address to the Prince of Wales, calling upon him
(without waiting for a Regency Bill) to assume the
Government of the Irish nation, “and to exercise
and administer all legal power, jurisdiction and prerogatives
to the Crown and Government thereof belonging” words
borrowed from the address by which in the Revolution
of 1688 William of Orange was requested to assume the
Crown. Happily, the Viceroy declined to present
the address, and a deputation sent from Ireland to
present it found on their arrival that the king had
recovered; but the incident might have led to a conflict
upon a matter so important as the exercise of the
royal power.
The fact is that the word “supremacy,”
so often used in this controversy, is one of ambiguous
meaning. Parliament is supreme in the United
Kingdom, Parliament is likewise supreme in New Zealand;
but the two supremacies are of widely different kinds.
Supremacy consists of two ingredients authority
to enact and power to enforce; and without the latter
the former is little more than a legal figment, which
may have no more practical importance than the theoretical
right of veto which is retained by the Crown.
Mr. Balfour, speaking on the second reading debate
of the 1893 Bill, referred to this matter as follows:
“Legally, of course, the Imperial
Parliament would be supreme: no one has
doubted it. But what layman takes the slightest
interest in these paper supremacies? For
my part I take no more interest in the question
of whether the Imperial Parliament is on paper superior
to the Irish Parliament, than I do as to the order
of precedence at a London dinner party.
The thing is of no public interest or importance
whatever. What we want to know is where the power
lies. Who is going to exercise supremacy?
Who is going to be the de facto ruler
of Ireland?”
Special importance attaches to these
considerations owing to the heavy liabilities undertaken
by this country in respect of land purchase in Ireland.
At the present time many millions of British money
are sunk in Irish land, and the amount may increase
to a sum approaching two hundred millions. The
tenants now pay their annuities because, in the last
resort, the Government can turn them out. Under
Home Rule the powers of Government would rest with
men who have led “no rent” agitations in
the past, and who would be dependent upon the votes
of those personally interested in repudiating the
debt. The British Treasury can hardly run such
a risk; and some sort of concurrent control, with all
its evils and risks, seems to be necessary. And
yet financial independence is the first essential
to genuine autonomy.
But, it may be said, if the Irish
Government go beyond the law, the Irish Courts may
be asked to interfere; and in the event of their refusal,
the Bill provides an appeal to the Judicial Committee
in London. No doubt it does, but in practice
the person aggrieved might have very great difficulty
in making the remedy effective. He must obtain
a decision in his favour from the Judicial Committee
of the Privy Council, at no small cost of money and
personal odium; and the decision of that “alien”
tribunal (as it would be called) must then be enforced
under the jurisdiction of a Government which (on the
hypothesis which we are considering) would be unfriendly,
by judges and executive officers appointed and perhaps
removable by that authority, and in the midst of a
population hostile to “foreign” interference.
Is it extravagant to suppose that the complainant
would not gain much by his appeal to Cæsar?
And even if we suppose the Irish Legislature
and Executive to confine themselves within the letter
of the Act, are the checks of any real value?
The Irish Parliament might still interfere with contracts,
or might validate contracts now held to be void as
contrary to public policy. They might defeat
the Mortmain Acts. They might deal as they thought
fit with internal trade; and the great industries of
Belfast and its neighbourhood might find their views
on trade questions of no avail. The Irish Legislature
might create new offences and institute new tribunals;
and the reference in the Bill to “due process
of law” would not necessarily secure trial by
jury or by an impartial tribunal.
It is said that legislation of this
character would be subject to the veto of the Crown.
But that veto is to be exercised on the advice of the
Irish Ministry subject to any instructions given by
the Sovereign; and so long as an Irish Legislature
is entitled to withhold Irish supply, a veto against
the advice of the Irish ministry would surely tend
to become impossible.
Again, it is said that an unjust law
passed by the Irish Parliament might be repealed by
the Imperial Parliament. Doubtless the technical
right would exist, as in the case of the Colonies;
but no one dreams that, with “responsible”
government existing in Ireland and Irish representatives
at Westminster, it would in practice be used.
The Imperial Government has never been known to interfere
with the legislation of a self-governing colony except
where Imperial interests are concerned, or where a
fraud on the colony can be established; and the
same rule would obtain in the case of Ireland.
Lastly, it is said that in the last
resort there is the British Army. But if the
civil power in Ireland does not call in the military
force, how can the latter be used to enforce the law?
Are the forces to be controlled from England, and
what is this but a counter revolution? It is
hardly worth while to liberate Ireland from the peaceful
rule of the Imperial Government in order to govern
her by military force.
But in fact the so-called “safeguards”
would not last. Professor Dicey and Professor
Morgan, writing from opposite sides of the controversy,
agree in holding that no colony would tolerate them
for a moment; and it is incredible that Ireland, with
a Parliament of her own, would submit to them for
more than a few years. Suppose the majority of
the Irish Legislature to grow weary of the “safeguards,”
and to demand their repeal. The Imperial ministry
might refuse, but the reply of the Irish ministry
(if in command of a majority in the Irish House of
Commons) would be to resign and to make the government
of Ireland impossible except by force. And if
Ireland were still represented in the Imperial Parliament,
the new “sorrows of Ireland” would find
eloquent and insistent expression there. What,
then, would England do? What could she do, except,
after a futile struggle, to give way? The truth
is, that if you part with the executive power, all
checks and “safeguards” are futile.
Mr. Redmond eagerly “accepts every one of
them,” and will accept others if desired; for
he knows that they must prove ineffective. “If,”
said Lord Derby in 1887, “Ireland and England
are not to be one, Ireland must be treated like Canada
or Australia. All between is delusion or fraud.”
IRISH REPRESENTATION AT WESTMINSTER.
The hybrid form of government proposed
in the Home Rule Bills of 1886 and 1893 gave rise
to a further difficulty, and one which went far towards
wrecking them both. Should Ireland under Home
Rule be represented at Westminster by its members
and representative peers? Under a system of Gladstonian
Home Rule there appear to be only three possible answers
to this question. The Irish representatives may
be excluded altogether, they may be retained altogether,
or they may be retained in diminished numbers and
with some limitation on their voting powers.
The total exclusion clause in the
Bill of 1886 was one of the most unpopular parts of
an unpopular Bill. It was immediately urged that
this arrangement was virtually equivalent to separation,
and Mr. Gladstone admitted that the argument had
force. Since 1886 public sentiment has advanced
in the direction of a closer Imperial unity, and it
is unlikely that the country will recur in 1912 to
a proposal which in 1886 was admitted to be intolerable.
Moreover, if the British Parliament is to retain control
of the whole foreign policy of the kingdom, and what
is likely to be of enormous importance in the future of
its whole fiscal policy, it would be manifestly unjust
to deny to Ireland a voice and vote in such matters.
How would it be possible, for instance, to discuss
the effect upon agriculture of a Tariff Reform Budget
in the absence of competent representatives of the
Irish farmers, or to consider the yearly grant to
be made (as it is said) in aid of Irish finance without
the assistance of any representatives of Ireland?
A recognition of the difficulties
in the way of total exclusion led Mr. Gladstone to
propose, in 1893, what was known as the “popping-in-and-out
clause,” under which Irish members would have
sat at Westminster, but would have voted only on Imperial
measures. The best criticism of this attempt
to distinguish between local and Imperial matters was
supplied on another occasion by Mr. Gladstone himself:
“I have thought
much, reasoned much, and inquired much with regard
to that distinction,
but I have arrived at the conclusion that it
cannot be drawn.
I believe it passes the wit of man.”
To distinguish between matters which
might and those which could not affect Ireland was
impossible to the ordinary man, and the device of
committing all matters of special difficulty to the
decision of Mr. Speaker had not then its present vogue.
Further, it was obvious that under such a system a
British Ministry might have on one day, when English
or Scottish affairs were under discussion, a commanding
majority; but on the next, when a vote possibly affecting
the sister island was in question, might find itself
labouring in the trough of the sea; while on the third
day, that vote having been disposed of and the Irish
members having taken their leave, it might rise once
more on the crest of the wave. The proposal was
too ludicrous to be long defended. The sense
of humour of the House prevailed over Mr. Gladstone’s
earnestness, and he fell back on inclusion for all
purposes.
But inclusion for all purposes had
its own difficulties. Under the Gladstonian system
the Imperial Parliament would have considered, not
only matters affecting the whole kingdom, but also
purely English or purely Scottish affairs; and to
give to the Irish representatives the control in their
own Parliament of purely Irish affairs, and also a
voice at Westminster on matters affecting England or
Scotland only, was obviously unjust. Such a power
would have been used, not for the benefit of England
or Scotland, but as an instrument for wresting further
concessions for Ireland.
“I will never be a party,”
said Mr. Gladstone at one time, “to allowing
the Irish members to manage their own affairs in Dublin,
and at the same time to come over here and manage
British affairs. Such an arrangement would
not be a Bill to grant self-government to Ireland,
but one to remove self-government from England; it
would create a subordinate Parliament indeed,
but it would be the one at Westminster, and not
that in Dublin."
The problem seems insoluble because,
under a hybrid (or Gladstonian) system of Home Rule,
it is insoluble. If a clear line is taken, there
is no difficulty under this head. If full “responsible”
or colonial government is granted, clearly representation
in the Imperial Parliament (I do not now speak of
a federal assembly) is an anomaly. On the other
hand, if nothing more is in question than the extension
of local government generally known as Devolution,
then adequate representation in the Imperial Parliament
is a matter of course. If a federal government
is established, each member of the Federation must
needs be represented in the federal Parliament; but
in that case there must be no attempt to entrust to
the same assembly both the duties of the federal Parliament
and those of a Legislature for one of the federating
states. It was this attempt to treat the Imperial
Parliament as the local or state Legislature for Great
Britain, and also as the federal Parliament for Great
Britain and Ireland, which was fatal to Mr. Gladstone’s
proposals.
FEDERALISM.
These considerations bring us face
to face with Federalism, or, to use the phrase which
to so many perplexed Liberals has seemed to point the
way to safety, “Home Rule all round.”
The expression covers a wide field, and before any
opinion can be pronounced upon the proposal, it is
essential to know what its advocates in fact desire.
To some the phrase means nothing less
than Gladstonian Home Rule “all round,”
in other words that we should meet the objections to
dissolving the legislative and executive Union with
Ireland by dissolving also the older Union with Scotland,
and even (for some do not shrink from the reductio
ad absurdum) the yet older unity of England and
Wales. Consider what this means. For more
than two hundred years the English and Scottish races
have been united by a constitutional bond strengthened
by mutual respect and good feeling, and Scotsmen, like
Englishmen, have taken their part in the government
of these islands. If in the division of labour
and of honours there has been a balance of advantage,
it has not been against the virile Scottish race, from
which have sprung so many of our great soldiers and
administrators, so many leaders of the nation.
And such a combination is to be broken up, and Scotland
to become a colony, because Ireland, unwilling to bear
her share in the duties of government, desires to
be reduced to that status! To such a proposal
Mr. Gladstone’s phrase about Home Rule applies
in all its force:
“Can any sensible man, can any
rational man, suppose that at this time of day,
in this condition of the world, we are going to disintegrate
the great capital institutions of this country for
the purpose of making ourselves ridiculous in
the sight of all mankind, and crippling any power
we possess for bestowing benefits through legislation
on the country to which we belong?”
The proposal would be incredibly stupid,
if it were not recklessly mischievous.
But to most advocates of the federal
system the word means less than this; and the conception,
usually vaguely expressed, is that the relations of
England, Scotland, and Ireland, should be something
like those of the communities which make up (to quote
instances commonly given) the German Empire, the Swiss
Federation, the United States of America, or the British
self-governing dominions of Canada, Australia, and
South Africa. So expressed, the aspiration for
a federal union deserves respectful consideration.
In the first place, it must not be
forgotten that no proposal of this nature has yet
been put forward, even in general terms, by any English
or Irish Party. Mr. John Redmond, the leader of
the Irish Nationalists, has indeed said that he and
his friends “were only asking what had already
been given in twenty-eight different portions of the
Empire:" and a speaker usually more careful in
his language lately suggested to his audience
that they should
“ask the twenty-eight
Home Rule Parliaments if the Empire would be
split in pieces if there
were a twenty-ninth.”
But in order to make up the number
of Parliaments and Legislatures within the Empire
to twenty-eight it is necessary to include in one
category the Parliament of the United Kingdom, the
colonial Parliaments of Newfoundland and New Zealand,
the federal Parliaments of Canada and Australia, the
provincial or state Legislatures (widely differing
from one another in their constitution and powers)
comprised in those Federations, the Union of South
Africa and its constituent provinces, and the tiny
assemblies surviving in the Channel Islands and the
Isle of Man. From a reference so vague and confused
no inference as to the real meaning or desire of either
speaker can safely be drawn.
But let us put aside, with the foreign
confederacies (which have in most cases been achieved
or maintained by armed conflict), the practically
independent Parliaments within the British Empire,
and confine ourselves to the Federations of Canada
and Australia, and to the Union (sometimes incorrectly
called a Federation) of South Africa.
In the first place, it is not immaterial
to observe that each of the Legislatures here referred
to resulted, not from the dissolution of an existing
union, but from the voluntary assumption by communities
formerly independent of one another of a closer bond.
In other words, there was in each case a real Jaedus
or treaty, not imposed by the Imperial power, but
having a local origin and springing from the need of
common action. The operative force was centripetal;
and as the force continues to operate, the tendency
of the mass is towards a chemical in lieu of a mechanical
fusion. But in the case of the United Kingdom a
change from organic union to Federation would be the
beginning of dissolution; and the centrifugal force,
once set in motion, might lead further in the same
direction.
Again, there can be no true federation
without (1) provincial legislatures and executives,
(2) a central Parliament and executive, (3) a careful
definition of the powers of each, and (4) a federal
court to which should be entrusted the duty of determining
questions arising between the federal and provincial
governments and legislatures. If, therefore,
provincial or state Governments are created for Ireland
and for Scotland, a like Government should logically
be created for England. Are we prepared to see
four (or, if Wales be added, five) legislatures, and
four (or five) executives, in these islands? Have
we considered the possible effect on our whole system
of government, on the theory of Cabinet responsibility
to Parliament, on the powers of the House of Commons
over grievance and supply? Must not each unit
in a Federation be put as regards financial matters
upon a like footing; and, if so, can Ireland bear
her share? Is federation consistent with the predominance
of one state, England, in wealth and population?
These questions are vital, and none of them have received
consideration. By declaring in general terms
for Federalism you go but a little way.
And if we treat the proposal for Federation
as indicating a desire to adopt a constitution under
which the relations of the United Kingdom to each
of its constituent parts would be as the relation of
some one of the three self-governing Dominions to
the states or provinces of which it is composed, the
question remains, which of those Dominions should be
adopted as a model? For they differ not only in
form but in essence.
Under the British North America Act,
1867, and the amending statutes, there is “one
Parliament for Canada” (sec, while each
province has its Legislature. Each provincial
Legislature is empowered exclusively to make laws
in relation to certain specified subjects (including
property and civil rights and the administration of
justice), and also in relation to “all matters
of a merely local or private nature in the province”;
while the Dominion Parliament may “make laws
for the peace, order, and good government of Canada
in relation to all matters not coming within”
the classes of subjects assigned exclusively to the
provincial Legislatures. The division of functions
has given rise to much confusion and litigation; but,
speaking generally, the trend of judicial decision
has been towards a wide interpretation of the provincial
powers. The “residuary powers” are
in the Dominion Parliament.
The constitution of the Commonwealth
of Australia, as defined by the Commonwealth of Australia
Constitution Act, 1900, is of a different character.
The Federal Parliament is entrusted with power to make
laws with respect to a number of subjects divided
into no less than 39 classes (sec; the State
Legislatures have concurrent powers of legislation,
but in case of conflict the law of the Commonwealth
is to prevail over the State law (sec.
The “residuary powers” are in this case
left to the States. There is power to alter the
Constitution with the consent of a majority of the
electors in a majority of the States and of a majority
of the electors of the Commonwealth (sec a
power which has been freely used.
The case of South Africa is sometimes
cited as a precedent for loosening the bonds in the
United Kingdom. It is a strong precedent for closer
union. The South Africa Act, 1909, created in
fact as well as in name, not a Federation but a true
Legislative Union. Under the Act, the South African
colonies were “united in a legislative union
under one government under the name of the Union of
South Africa” (sec. The legislative
power is vested in the Parliament of the Union (sec, which has full power to make laws for the peace,
order, and good government of the Union (sec.
In each province (formerly a colony) there is an administrator
appointed by the Governor-General of the Union in
Council (sec, and a Provincial Council (sec; but the powers of the Provincial Councils are
confined within narrow limits (sec, and their
ordinances (they are not called laws) have effect
within the province as long as and so far as they are
not repugnant to any Act of the Union Parliament (sec. The Supreme Courts of the old colonies become
provincial divisions of the Supreme Court of South
Africa (sec, and the colonial property and debts
are transferred to the Union (sect-124).
In fact, in South Africa, where, as in Ireland, the
distinction in the past has been racial and not territorial,
Union and not Federation has gained the day. It
is safe to prophesy that the coming proposals of the
Government will not follow the South African plan.
DEVOLUTION.
The South African precedent leads
naturally to a few observations on the proposals for
the extension of local self-government, usually classified
under the head of Devolution. These proposals
differ, not in degree only but in kind, from schemes
for the granting of responsible government, or Gladstonian
Home Rule. Under all devolutionary schemes, properly
so-called, the central Parliament and executive remain
the ultimate depositaries of power; and the powers
entrusted to local bodies are administrative only,
and can be resumed at will. The Acts by which
County Councils were set up, first in Great Britain
and afterwards in Ireland, were steps in this direction.
The Welsh Intermediate Education Act, 1889, was another.
The establishment by the Agriculture and Technical
Instruction (Ireland) Act, 1899, of a Council of Agriculture,
as Agricultural Board, and a Board of Technical Instruction,
was a third. By these statutes wide powers are
delegated to representative bodies directly or indirectly
elected by popular vote; but in each case the delegated
powers are strictly defined, their exercise is made
subject to central control, and the right of Parliament
to modify or withdraw any of them is absolute and
unquestioned. The appointment by the House of
Commons of a Grand Committee for Scottish Bills is
another experiment of a similar character, though
on different lines. Such delegations of power
are consistent with the maintenance in its entirety
of the Union of the Kingdom, and there is no reason
whatever why further progress should not be made in
the same direction. The events of 1907 are evidence
that Devolution, regarded merely as a means of satisfying
the political cry for Home Rule, is indeed “dead.”
But when the din of political battle has once more
passed by, it may be possible to obtain consideration
for a moderate and clearly defined scheme of delegation
which, if applied not exclusively to Ireland, but to
the whole country, might relieve the House of Commons
of much of its work, and strengthen the habit of local
self-government throughout the United Kingdom.