An English observer of agricultural
conditions in 1893 finds that agricultural unrest
was not peculiar to the United States in the last
quarter of the nineteenth century, but existed in all
the more advanced countries of the world:
Almost everywhere, certainly in England, France, Germany,
Italy, Scandinavia, and the United States, the agriculturists, formerly so
instinctively conservative, are becoming fiercely discontented, declare they
gained less by civilization than the rest of the community, and are looking
about for remedies of a drastic nature. In England they are hoping for aid from
councils of all kinds; in France they have put on protective duties which have
been increased in vain twice over; in Germany they put on and relaxed similar
duties and are screaming for them again; in Scandinavia Denmark more
particularly they limit the aggregation of land; and in the United States they
create organizations like the Grangers, the Farmers Leagues, and the
Populists."
It is to general causes, indeed, that
one must turn before trying to find the local circumstances
which aggravated the unrest in the United States,
or at least appeared to do so. The application
of power first steam, then electricity to
machinery had not only vastly increased the productivity
of mankind but had stimulated invention to still wider
activity and lengthened the distance between man and
that gaunt specter of famine which had dogged his
footsteps from the beginning. With a constantly,
growing supply of the things necessary for the maintenance
of life, population increased tremendously: England,
which a few centuries before had been overcrowded
with fewer than four million’ people, was now
more bountifully feeding and clothing forty millions.
Perhaps, all in all, mankind was better off than it
had ever been before; yet different groups maintained
unequal progress. The tillers of the soil as
a whole remained more nearly in their primitive condition
than did the dwellers of the city. The farmer,
it is true, produced a greater yield of crops, was
surrounded by more comforts, and was able to enjoy
greater leisure than his kind had ever done before.
The scythe and cradle had been supplanted by the mower
and reaper; horse harrows, cultivators, and rakes
had transferred much of the physical exertion of farming
to the draft animals. But, after all, the farmer
owed less to steam and electricity than the craftsman
and the artisan of the cities.
The American farmer, if he read the
census reports, might learn that rural wealth had
increased from nearly $4,000,000,000 in 1850 to not
quite $16,000,000,000 in 1890; but he would also discover
that in the same period urban wealth had advanced
from a little over $3,000,000,000 to more than $49,000,000,000.
Forty years before the capital of rural districts
comprised more than half that of the whole country,
now it formed only twenty-five per cent. The
rural population had shown a steady proportionate
decrease: when the first census was taken in 1790,
the dwellers of the country numbered more than ten
times those of the city, but at the end of the nineteenth
century they formed only about one-third of the total.
Of course the intelligent farmer might have observed
that food for the consumption of all could be produced
by the work of fewer hands, and vastly more bountifully
as well, and so he might have explained the relative
decline of rural population and wealth; but when the
average farmer saw his sons and his neighbors’
sons more and more inclined to seek work in town and
leave the farm, he put two and two together and came
to the conclusion that farming was in a perilous state.
He heard the boy who had gone to the city boast that
his hours were shorter, his toil less severe, and
his return in money much greater than had been the
case on the farm; and he knew that this was true.
Perhaps the farmer did not realize that he had some
compensations: greater security of position and
a reasonable expectation that old age would find him
enjoying some sort of home, untroubled by the worry
which might attend the artisan or shopkeeper.
Whether or not the American farmer
realized that the nineteenth century had seen a total
change in the economic relations of the world, he did
perceive clearly that something was wrong in his own
case. The first and most impressive evidence
of this was to be found in the prices he received
for what he had to sell. From 1883 to 1889 inclusive
the average price of wheat was seventy-three cents
a bushel, of corn thirty-six cents, of oats twenty-eight
cents. In 1890 crops were poor in most of the
grain areas, while prosperous times continued to keep
the consuming public of the manufacturing regions
able to buy; consequently corn and oats nearly doubled
in price, and wheat advanced 20 per cent. Nevertheless,
such was the shortage, except in the case of corn,
that the total return was smaller than it had been
for a year or two before. In 1891 bumper crops
of wheat, corn, oats, rye, and barley drove the price
down on all except wheat and rye, but not to the level
of 1889. Despite a much smaller harvest in 1892
the decline continued, to the intense disgust of the
farmers of Nebraska and Minnesota who failed to note
that the entire production of wheat in the world was
normal in that year, that considerable stores of the
previous crop had been held over and that more than
a third of the yield in the United States was sent
forth to compete everywhere with the crops of Argentine,
Russia, and the other grain producing countries.
No wonder the average farmer of the Mississippi basin
was ready to give ear to any one who could suggest
a remedy for his ills.
Cotton, which averaged nearly eleven
cents a pound for the decade ending in 1890, dropped
to less than nine cents in 1891 and to less than eight
in 1892. Cattle, hogs, sheep, horses, and mules
brought more in the late than in the early eighties,
yet these, too, showed a decline about 1890.
The abnormal war-time price of wool which was more
than one dollar a pound in October, 1864, dropped
precipitately with peace, rose a little just before
the panic of 1873, and then declined with almost no
reaction until it reached thirty-three cents for the
highest grade in 1892.
The “roaring eighties,”
with all their superficial appearance of prosperity,
had apparently not brought equal cheer to all.
And then came the “heart-breaking nineties.”
In February, 1893, the Philadelphia and Reading Railroad
Company failed, a break in the stock market followed,
and an old-fashioned panic seized the country in its
grasp. A period of hitherto unparalleled speculative
frenzy came thus to an end, and sober years followed
in which the American people had ample opportunity
to contemplate the evils arising from their economic
debauch.
Prices of agricultural products continued
their downward trend. Wheat touched bottom in
1894 with an average price of forty-nine cents; corn,
two years later, reached twenty-one cents. All
the other grains were likewise affected. Middling
cotton which had sold at eight and a half cents a
pound in 1893, dropped below seven cents the following
year, recovered until it reached nearly eight cents
in 1896, and was at its lowest in 1898 at just under
six cents. Of all the marketable products of
the farm, cattle, hay, and hogs alone maintained the
price level of the decade prior to 1892. Average
prices, moreover, do not fully indicate the small
return which many farmers received. In December,
1891, for instance, the average value of a bushel of
corn was about forty cents, but in Nebraska, on January
1, 1892, corn brought only twenty-six cents.
When, a few years later, corn was worth, according
to the statistics, just over twenty-one cents, it
was literally cheaper to burn it in Kansas or Nebraska
than to cart it to town, sell it, and buy coal with
the money received; and this is just what hundreds
of despairing farmers did. Even crop shortage
did little to increase the price of the grain that
was raised. When a drought seriously diminished
the returns in Ohio, Indiana, and Michigan in 1895,
the importation from States farther west prevented
any rise in price.
Prices dropped, but the interest on
mortgages remained the same. One hundred and
seventy-four bushels of wheat would pay the interest
at 8 per cent on a $2000 mortgage in 1888, when the
price of wheat was higher than it had been for ten
years and higher than it was to be again for a dozen
years. In 1894 or 1895 when the price was hovering
around fifty cents, it took 320 bushels to pay the
same interest. Frequently the interest was higher
than 8 per cent, and outrageous commissions on renewals
increased the burden of the farmer. The result
was one foreclosure after another. The mortgage
shark was identified as the servant of the “Wall
Street Octopus,” and between them there was
little hope for the farmer. In Kansas, according
to a contemporary investigator, “the whole
western third of the State was settled by a boom in
farm lands. Multitudes of settlers took claims
without means of their own, expecting to pay for the
land from the immediate profits of farming. Multitudes
of them mortgaged the land for improvements, and multitudes
more expended the proceeds of mortgages in living.
When it was found that the proceeds of farming in
that part of the State were very uncertain, at best,
the mortgages became due. And in many instances
those who had been nominally owners remained upon the
farms as tenants after foreclosure. These are
but the natural effects in reaction from a tremendous
boom.” In eastern Kansas, where settlement
was older, the pressure of hard times was withstood
with less difficulty. It was in western Kansas,
by the way, that Populism had its strongest following;
and, after the election of 1892, a movement to separate
the State into two commonwealths received serious
consideration.
Even more inexorable than the holder
of the mortgage or his agent was the tax collector.
It was easy to demonstrate that the farmer, with little
or nothing but his land, his stock, and a meager outfit
of implements and furniture, all readily to be seen
and assessed, paid taxes higher in proportion to his
ability to pay than did the business man or the corporation.
Although his equity in the land he owned might be
much less than its assessed value, he was not allowed
to make any deduction for mortgages. The revenue
of the Federal Government was raised wholly by indirect
taxes levied principally upon articles of common consumption;
and the farmer and other people of small means paid
an undue share of the burden in the form of higher
prices demanded for commodities.
Low prices for his produce, further
depressed by the rapacity of the railroads and the
other intermediaries between the producer and the
consumer, mortgages with high interest rates, and an
inequitable system of taxation formed the burden of
the farmer’s complaint during the last two decades
of the nineteenth century. These grievances and
all sorts of remedies proposed for them were discussed
in farmers’ gatherings, in agricultural weeklies,
even in city dailies, and ultimately in legislative
chambers. Investigations demonstrated that, even
when reduced to a minimum, the legitimate grounds
for complaint were extensive; and the resultant reports
suggested a variety of remedies. Generally, however,
popular sentiment swung around again to the tack it
had taken in the late seventies: the real cure
for all the evils was more money. Wall Street
and the national banks could suck the blood from the
western community because of their monopoly of the
money supply. According to one irate editor,
“Few people are aware of the boundless advantages
that the national banks have under our present accursed
system. They have usurped the credit of the people
and are fattening a thousand-fold annually from the
unlimited resources at their command.”
Another editor wrote:
We find the following printed card
on our desk: “The last report of the Secretary
of the Treasury shows the banks as loaning $1,970,022,687”!
Four times the amount of money there is to loan.
Four interests in every dollar! They are drawing
from the people enough to run the National Government.
How long will it take them to gather in all the money
of the nation? This does not include the amounts
loaned by state, private, and savings banks.
Add to this the billions of dollars of other loans
and think if it is any wonder times are hard.
Will the American people never wake up to the fact
that they are being pauperized? Four people are
paying interest upon each dollar you have in your pocket if
you have any. Wake up! Wake up!
Whatever the ultimate effects of an
inflated and consequently depreciated currency might
be, the debtor class, to which a large portion of
the Western farmers belonged, would obviously benefit
immediately by the injection of large quantities of
money into the circulating medium. The purchasing
power of money would be lower; hence the farmer would
receive more in dollars and cents and would be in a
better position to pay his standing debts. Whether
or not the rise in the prices of his products would
be offset or more than offset by the increased prices
which he would have to pay for the things he purchased
would depend upon the relative rate at which different
commodities adjusted themselves to the new scale of
money value. In the end, of course, other things
being equal, there would be a return of old conditions;
but the farmers did not look so far ahead. Hence
it was that less attention was paid to taxation, to
railroad rates and discriminations, to elevator companies,
to grain gamblers, or to corporations as such; and
the main force of the agrarian movements from 1875
onward was exerted, first for an increased paper currency
and then for free silver.